NZLII Home | Databases | WorldLII | Search | Feedback

University of Otago Law Theses and Dissertations

You are here:  NZLII >> Databases >> University of Otago Law Theses and Dissertations >> 2006 >> [2006] UOtaLawTD 2

Database Search | Name Search | Recent Articles | Noteup | LawCite | Download | Help

Caughey, Jill --- "A Tangible Distinction? - Intangibles and the Public Benefit Trust in the Commerce Act 1986" [2006] UOtaLawTD 2

Last Updated: 15 September 2023

A T A N G I B L E D I S T I N C T I 0 N?

Intangibles and the Public Benefit Test in the Commerce Act 1986

Jill Caughey

A dissertation submitted in partial fulfilment of the degree of Bachelor of Laws (Honours) at the University of Otago, Dunedin

October 2005

Acknowledgements

To my supervisor, Rex Ahdar, thanks for your comments and encouraging me to develop my own ideas. I would also like to acknowledge Michael Pickford at the Commerce Commission and Grant David at Chapman Tripp, who were so eager to help in any way they could. Thanks to Niven Winchester in the economics department for answering my questions about general equilibrium models. Si, thanks for your comments, humour and the illustration of how not to do a dissertation. Special thanks to Nicki for volunteering to proofread this paper - I hope it hasn't put you off competition law! Finally, a huge thank you to my family, for all their support and encouragement throughout my education, and my friends for making my time in Dunedin such a fantastic and memorable experience.

Table of Contents

Acknowledgments
ii
Table of Contents
iii
List of Figures and Tables
v
Table of Cases
vi
Introduction
1
Chapter 1: Defining “Intangible Benefit”
4
1.1 History of usage
4
1.2 Possible definitions
5
1.2.1 An abstract benefit
5
1.2.2 A benefit that is difficult to quantify
5
1.2.3 A non-market benefit
7
1.2.4 An indirect benefit
7
1.2.5 A non-efficiency benefit
8
1.3 Approach of the Commerce Commission
9
1.3.1 General approach
9
1.3.2 Benefits that have been described as intangible benefits
11
1.3.3 Benefits that have been described as tangible benefits
12
1.3.4 Consistency of the Commission's approach
13
1.4 The common features of intangible benefits
14
1.5 The approach utilised in this paper: a spectrum of tangibility
16
1.5.1 Category 1: Vague claims with far reaching consequences
17
1.5.2 Category 2: Externality arguments
18
1.5.3 Category 3: Quality improvements
19
1.5.4 Category 4: Improving New Zealand's export performance
19
1.5.5 Other benefits
20
1.5.6 The spectrum of tangibility
21
Chapter 2: The Treatment of Intangible Benefits
23
2.1 Quantified intangibles
24
2.2 Unquantified intangibles
25
2.2.1 Category 1: Vague claims with far reaching consequences
25
2.2.2 Category 2: Externality arguments
28

List of Figures and Tables

Figures
Figure 1: The spectrum of tangibility
6
Figure 2: The categorisation approach to the spectrum of tangibility
22
Figure 3: Increased choice for consumers
34
Tables
Table 1: Categories of benefits

17

Table of Cases

Commerce Commission Decisions

Amcor - NZ Forest Products Ltd, Re (1987) 1 NZBLC (Com) 104,233

Ansett (see Air New Zealand Ltd/Ansett Holdings Ltd)

Air New Zealand Ltd/Ansett Holdings Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 278, 3 April 1996 (Ansett)

Air New Zealand Ltd/Qantas Airways Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 511, 23 October 2003 (Qantas)

Brierley Investments Ltd/The Petroleum Corporation of New Zealand Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 215, 22 March 1988

Carter Holt Harvey Ltd/The Crown Commerce Commission Decision No 228, 5 April 1989

Closure of Whakatu and Advanced Works, Re (1987) 2 TCLR 215; (1987) 1 NZBLC

(Com) 104,200 (Whakatu)

Consortium of Meat Processing Companies Commerce Commission Decision No 273, 2 February 1995

Elders Resources NZFP Ltd/The Crown Commerce Commission Decision No 227, 21 March 1989

Electricity Corporation of New Zealand Ltd/Contact Energy Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 277, 30 January 1996

Electricity Governance Board Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 473, 30 September 2002

Enerco New Zealand Ltd/Progas Systems Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 272, 22 December 1993

Fisher & Paykel Ltd (No 2), Re (1989) 2 NZBLC (Com) 104,377

Fletcher Challenge Ltd - New Zealand Forest Products Ltd, Re (1988) 1 NZBLC (Com) 104,283

Forest Products (see New Zealand Forest Products Ltd - UEB Industries Ltd, Re) Goodman Fielder Ltd - Wattie Industries Ltd, Re (1987) 1 NZBLC (Com) 104,108 Grape Growers (see The New Zealand Grape Growers Council Inc, Re)

Hoyts Corporation Holdings Operations (New Zealand) Ltd/Pacer Kerridge Corporation Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 265, 24 May 1991

Life Underwriters Association of New Zealand Inc Commerce Commission Decision No 223, 15 December 1988

Kiwi Co-operative Dairies Ltd/Moa-Nui Co-operative Dairies Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 267, 9 April 1992

Kiwifruit (see New Zealand Kiwifruit Exporters Association (Inc) - New Zealand Kiwifruit Coolstores Association (Inc), Re)

Midland Health (see Midland Regional Health Authority/Health Waikato Ltd)

Midland Regional Health Authority/Health Waikato Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 275, 1 August 1995 (Midland Health)

Natural Gas 1 (see Natural Gas Corporation of New Zealand Ltd/Wanganui District Council)

Natural Gas 2 (see Natural Gas Corporation of New Zealand Ltd/Enerco New Zealand Ltd)

Natural Gas Corporation of New Zealand Ltd/Wanganui District Council Commerce Commission Decision No 269, 29 October 1992 (Natural Gas 1)

Natural Gas Corporation of New Zealand Ltd/Enerco New Zealand Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 270, 22 November 1993 (Natural Gas 2)

Natural Gas Waikato Ltd/Hamilton City Council Commerce Commission Decision No 217, 24 May 1988

Newcall Communications Ltd/TeamTalk Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 356, 17 May 1999

New Zealand Forest Products Ltd - UEB Industries Ltd, Re (1987) 1 NZBLC (Com) 104,159 (Forest Products)

New Zealand Kiwifruit Exporters Association (Inc) - New Zealand Kiwifruit Coolstores Association (Inc), Re (1989) 2 NZBLC (Com) 104,485 (Kiwifruit)

New Zealand Rugby Football Union Inc Commerce Commission Decision No 281, 17 December 1996 (NZRFU 1)

New Zealand Rugby Football Union Inc Commerce Commission Decision No 580, 2 June 2006 (NZRFU 2)

New Zealand Stock Exchange Commerce Commission Decision No 231, 10 May 1989 (NZSE 1)

New Zealand Stock Exchange Commerce Commission Decision No 232, 10 May 1989 (NZSE 2)

New Zealand Vegetable Growers Federation Inc Commerce Commission Decision No 206, 31 July 1987 (Vegetable Growers)

NZ Dairy 1 (see The New Zealand Co-operative Dairy Company Ltd/Auckland Co- operative Milk Producers Ltd)

NZ Dairy 2 (see The New Zealand Co-operative Dairy Company Ltd - Waikato Valley Co-operative Dairies Ltd, Re)

NZRFU 1 (see New Zealand Rugby Football Union Inc Commerce Commission Decision No 281)

NZRFU 2 (see New Zealand Rugby Football Union Inc Commerce Commission Decision No 580)

NZSE 1 (see New Zealand Stock Exchange Commerce Commission Decision No 231)

NZSE 2 (see New Zealand Stock Exchange Commerce Commission Decision No 232)

Omv New Zealand Ltd/Shell Exploration New Zealand Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 505, 1 September 2003

Petroleum Corporation of New Zealand Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 233, 16 June 1989

Powerco Ltd/Egmont Electricity Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 302, 21 July 1997

Qantas (see Air New Zealand Ltd/Qantas Airways Ltd)

Ravensdown Corporation Ltd/SouthFert Co-operative Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 279, 21 June 1996

Ruapehu Alpine Lifts Ltd/Turoa Ski Resorts Ltd (in receivership) Commerce Commission Decision No 410, 14 November 2000

SFE 1 (see Sydney Futures Exchange Ltd/Sydney Futures Exchange Clearing House Pty Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 271)

SFE 2 (see Sydney Futures Exchange Ltd/Sydney Futures Exchange Clearing House Pty Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 274)

South Pacific Tyres (New Zealand) Ltd/Frank George Allen Commerce Commission Decision No 247, 3 May 1990

Speedway Control Board of New Zealand (Inc), Re (1990) 2 NZBLC (Com) 104,485

Sydney Futures Exchange Ltd/Sydney Futures Exchange Clearing House Pty Ltd

Commerce Commission Decision No 271, 21 December 1993 (SFE 1)

Sydney Futures Exchange Ltd/Sydney Futures Exchange Clearing House Pty Ltd

Commerce Commission Decision No 274, 31 July 1995 (SFE 2)

Tasman Forestry Ltd/The Crown Commerce Commission Decision No 224, 24 February 1989

TeamTalk Ltd/Telecom New Zealand Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 393, 15 May 2000

Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd/The Crown Commerce Commission Decision No 254, 17 October 1990

The New Zealand Co-operative Dairy Company Ltd/Auckland Co-operative Milk Producers Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 216, 26 April 1988 (NZ Dairy 1)

The New Zealand Co-operative Dairy Company Ltd - Waikato Valley Co-operative Dairies Ltd, Re (1991) 2 NZBLC (Com) 104,592 (NZ Dairy 2)

The New Zealand Grape Growers Council Inc, Re (1991) 2 NZBLC (Com) 104,573 (Grape Growers)

Transpower New Zealand Ltd Commerce Commission Decision No 369, 13 August 1999

Vegetable Growers (see New Zealand Vegetable Growers Federation Inc) Whakatu (see Closure of Whakatu and Advanced Works, Re)

High Court and Court of Appeal Decisions

Air New Zealand v Commerce Commission (No 6) [2004] NZHC 1010; (2004) 11 TCLR 347 (Qantas (HC))

Fisher & Paykel Ltd v Commerce Commission [1990] NZHC 307; [1990] 2 NZLR 731 (Fisher & Paykel (HC))

New Zealand Co-operative Dairy Co Ltd v Commerce Commission [1992] 1 NZLR 601 (NZ Dairy 2 (HC))

NZ Dairy 2 (HC) (see New Zealand Co-operative Dairy Co Ltd v Commerce Commission)

Qantas (HC) (see Air New Zealand v Commerce Commission (No 6))

Ravensdown Corporation Ltd v Commerce Commission unreported, High Court Wellington, AP168/96, 16 December 1996, Panckhurst J and Professor R G Lattimore

Rugby Union Players’ Association Inc v Commerce Commission (No 2) [1997] 3 NZLR 301 (Rugby Union (HC))

Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission (1991) 4 TCLR 473 (Telecom (HC))

Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission [1992] NZCA 595; [1992] 3 NZLR 429 (Telecom (CA))

The New Zealand Vegetable Growers Federation (Inc) v The Commerce Commission (No 3) [1988] NZHC 437; (1988) 2 TCLR 582

Australian Decisions

Queensland Co-operative Milling Association Ltd, Defiance Holdings Ltd (Proposed Merger with Barnes Milling Ltd), Re; Defiance Holdings Ltd, Re (1976) 25 FLR 169; 8 ALR 481; ATPR 40-012

Introduction

The Commerce Act 1986 (the “Act”) is the primary piece of legislation governing competition law in New Zealand. Its objective is to “promote competition in markets for the long-term benefit of consumers in New Zealand”. To meet this end it seeks to constrain the accumulation of market power and prevent the abuse of monopoly power, and thereby plays an important role in regulating commercial trade practices and business acquisitions in New Zealand.

The scheme of the Commerce Act Ł986

Parts II and III of the Act prohibit certain activities on the grounds that they are anti- competitive. If these provisions are breached the person(s) involved are liable to pecuniary penalty. Under Part V of the Act, parties to a business acquisition or trade practice that would potentially breach the Act may apply to the Commission for an authorisation. An authorisation provides them with impunity from attack for being in breach of the Act.

For an authorisation to be granted in respect of anti-competitive arrangements and covenants, the benefit to the public must outweigh the detriment from the lessening

&RPPHUFH $FW V $ &RPSHWLWLRQ LV GHILQHG DV ´ZRUNDEOH RU HIIHFWLYH FRPSHWLWLRQµ UDWKHU WKDQ WKH WUDGLWLRQDO HFRQRPLF QRWLRQ RI SHUIHFW FRPSHWLWLRQ 3HUIHFW FRPSHWLWLRQ UHSUHVHQWV D PDUNHW VWUXFWXUH LQ ZKLFK QR SURGXFHU RU FRQVXPHU KDV WKH PDUNHW SRZHU WR LQIOXHQFH SULFHV OHDGLQJ WR D FRPSOHWHO\ HIILFLHQW RXWFRPH VHH 5REHUW )UDQN DQG %HQ %HUQDQNH 3ULQFLSOHV RI (FRQRPLFV UG HG 0F*UDZ +LOO ,UZLQ %RVWRQ DW +DO 9DULDQ ,QWHUPHGLDWH 0LFURHFRQRPLFV $ 0RGHUQ $SSURDFK WK HG :: 1RUWRQ 1HZ <RUN DW

66 DQG SURKLELW WKH HQWHULQJ RI FRQWUDFWV DUUDQJHPHQWV XQGHUVWDQGLQJV DQG FRYHQDQWV WKDW VXEVWDQWLDOO\ OHVVHQ FRPSHWLWLRQ V SURKLELWV ER\FRWWV V SURKLELWV WKH WDNLQJ DGYDQWDJH RI D VXEVWDQWLDO GHJUHH RI PDUNHW SRZHU IRU FHUWDLQ SXUSRVHV V SURKLELWV UHVDOH SULFH PDLQWHQDQFH DQG V SURKLELWV WKH DFTXLVLWLRQ RI EXVLQHVV DVVHWV RU VKDUHV WKDW ZRXOG KDYH WKH HIIHFW RI VXEVWDQWLDOO\ OHVVHQLQJ FRPSHWLWLRQ

&RPPHUFH $FW VV 6 GHDOV ZLWK UHVWULFWLYH WUDGH SUDFWLFHV DQG V FRYHUV EXVLQHVV DFTXLVLWLRQV 7KHUH LV DOVR WKH SRVVLELOLW\ RI LQMXQFWLRQV DQG GDPDJHV ERWK FRPSHQVDWRU\ DQG H[HPSODU\ EHLQJ DZDUGHG DQG LQ WKH FDVH RI EXVLQHVV DFTXLVLWLRQV WKHUH LV WKH IXUWKHU SRVVLELOLW\ RI GLYHVWLWXUH

&RPPHUFH $FW VV 6 VHWV RXW WKH SURYLVLRQV DOORZLQJ SHUVRQV WR DSSO\ IRU DQ DXWKRULVDWLRQ LQ UHVSHFW RI D UHVWULFWLYH WUDGH SUDFWLFH 6 HQDEOHV SHUVRQV WR DSSO\ IRU DQ DXWKRULVDWLRQ IRU D EXVLQHVV DFTXLVLWLRQ 1RW DOO FRQGXFW FDQ EH DXWKRULVHG ,Q SDUWLFXODU DFWLRQV SURKLELWHG XQGHU V IRU WDNLQJ DGYDQWDJH RI D VXEVWDQWLDO GHJUHH RI PDUNHW SRZHU IRU FHUWDLQ SXUSRVHV FDQQRW EH DXWKRULVHG

&RPPHUFH $FW VV $ 6 $ SHUWDLQV WR UHVWULFWLYH WUDGH SUDFWLFHV DQG V UHODWHV WR EXVLQHVV DFTXLVLWLRQV

in competition. Although the tests for the authorisation of boycotts, resale price maintenance and business acquisitions are worded slightly differently, requiring “such a benefit to the public” that they should be permitted, they have also been interpreted as requiring a balancing of public benefits against any public detriments flowing from the practice.

The benefits and detriments likely to arise from the practice or acquisition are determined by comparing two hypothetical situations; that which would arise with the merger (the factual) and that which would arise without the merger (the counterfactual). Whilst detriments are restricted to those arising in the relevant market, the Commerce Commission (the “Commission”) and courts have taken a much broader view as to what constitutes a relevant benefit. A “public benefit” has been described as “any gain to the public of New Zealand”, and the Commission and courts have indicated that there is no limitation as to the nature of the public benefit which can be claimed. However, for the public benefit to be accepted the applicant must provide proof of its existence and extent, and establish that there is a causal nexus between the benefit and the relevant conduct or merger. Because the Commission is only concerned with net benefits, any corresponding detriment must be deducted from the public benefit claim.

&RPPHUFH $FW V 0RUH SUHFLVHO\ WKH DSSOLFDWLRQ PXVW ´LQ DOO WKH FLUFXPVWDQFHV UHVXOW RU EH OLNHO\ WR UHVXOW LQ D EHQHILW WR WKH SXEOLF ZKLFK ZRXOG RXWZHLJK WKH OHVVHQLQJ LQ FRPSHWLWLRQ WKDW ZRXOG UHVXOW RU ZRXOG EH OLNHO\ WR UHVXOW RU LV GHHPHG WR UHVXOW WKHUHIURPµ

&RPPHUFH $FW VV E 0RUH SUHFLVHO\ LQ WKH FDVH RI ER\FRWWV DQG UHVDOH SULFH PDLQWHQDQFH WKH DSSOLFDWLRQ PXVW ´LQ DOO WKH FLUFXPVWDQFHV UHVXOW RU EH OLNHO\ WR UHVXOW LQ VXFK D EHQHILW WR WKH SXEOLFµ WKDW LW ´VKRXOG EH SHUPLWWHGµ VV 7KH UHTXLUHPHQW IRU EXVLQHVV DFTXLVLWLRQV LV WKDW WKH DFTXLVLWLRQ ´ZLOO UHVXOW RU ZLOO EH OLNHO\ WR UHVXOW LQ VXFK D EHQHILW WR WKH SXEOLF WKDW LW VKRXOG EH SHUPLWWHGµ V E

,Q UHVSHFW RI V VHH 1=6( DW > @ .LZL DW > @ &RQVRUWLXP DW > @ ,Q UHVSHFW RI V E VHH 1DWXUDO *DV DW > @ (QHUFR DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ 3RZHUFR DW

> @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ $OWKRXJK WKHUH LV QR DXWKRULW\ RQ V SUHVXPDEO\ WKH VDPH SULQFLSOHV ZRXOG DSSO\

)RU H[DPSOH VHH *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU DW > @ $PFRU DW > @ LL

7KH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ LV DQ LQGHSHQGHQW &URZQ HQWLW\ VHW XS WR ´SURPRWH G\QDPLF DQG UHVSRQVLYH PDUNHWV VR WKDW 1HZ =HDODQGHUV EHQHILW IURP FRPSHWLWLYH SULFHV EHWWHU TXDOLW\ DQG JUHDWHU FKRLFHµ &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ 2YHUYLHZ &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ

KWWS ZZZ FRPFRP JRYW Q] 7KH&RPPLVVLRQ 2YHUYLHZ DVS[! DFFHVVHG $XJXVW

&RQVRUWLXP DW > @ 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW

> @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @

:KDNDWX DW > @ L $PFRU DW > @ LLL 7HOHFRP +& DW

)RU H[DPSOH VHH *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU DW > @ > @ > @ :KDNDWX DW > @ YLL $PFRU DW > @ L[

^ @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH :KDNDWX DW > @ Y

)RU H[DPSOH VHH :KDNDWX DW > @ )RU H[DPSOH LI SRVLWLYH HQYLURQPHQWDO HIIHFWV DUH FODLPHG DV D EHQHILW DQ\ HQYLURQPHQWDO GHWULPHQW QHHGV WR EH GHGXFWHG IURP WKH HQYLURQPHQWDO EHQHILW WR JLYH D QHW HQYLURQPHQWDO EHQHILW ILJXUH ,I HQYLURQPHQWDO EHQHILWV DUH QRW FODLPHG HQYLURQPHQWDO GHWULPHQWV GR QRW QHHG WR EH GHGXFWHG IURP WKH EHQHILWV EHFDXVH WKH HQYLURQPHQWDO GHWULPHQWV ZRXOG QRW DULVH LQ WKH UHOHYDQW PDUNHW

The objective of this dissertation

In the last 10 years the Commission has begun to refer to a certain class of benefits as intangible. This dissertation aims to evaluate the treatment of these so-called intangible benefits, with a particular emphasis on considering whether they are ever given significant weight in the public benefit analysis. It canvasses all the authorisation decisions since the introduction of the Commerce Act in 1986, of which there have been 45 Commission decisions, 7 High Court decisions and 1 Court of Appeal decision.

Chapter One attempts to define what an intangible benefit is and sets out the approach to be utilised in Chapter Two to evaluate the treatment of intangible benefits. Chapter Three analyses whether intangibles can be treated differently from tangible benefits under the law as it now stands, and whether they should be considered as a matter of policy. Chapter Four presents three alternative methods of quantifying intangibles and considers the feasibility of using each of these methods. Finally, it is concluded that when assessing the weight to be given to a benefit, the Commission should no longer focus upon whether the benefit is tangible or intangible. It provides little or no assistance, and unnecessarily complicates the analysis.

)RU D KLVWRU\ RI WKH XVDJH RI WKH WHUP ´LQWDQJLEOHµ VHH 6HFWLRQ

6HH WKH 7DEOH RI &DVHV IRU IXUWKHU GHWDLOV

C H AP T E R 0 N E

Defining “Intangible Benefit”

Ł.Ł History of usage

The term “intangible benefit” has only come to be used by the Commerce Commission in recent years. Although it has only been used by the Commission in eight of the forty-five authorisation decisions since the enactment of the Act in 1986, it has been used in five of the last six decisions.

The first hint of a distinction between tangible and intangible benefits came in 1987 in Amcor where the Commission used the term “tangible public benefits” to describe certain benefits. However, the word “intangible” was not mentioned in a decision until 1991 in NZ Dairy 2, and even then it was the applicant, rather than the Commission, who used it. It was not until the Commission's decision in 1995 in Consortium that the Commission itself used the term “intangible”. Since Consortium, nine of the fifteen Commission decisions have drawn some sort of distinction between tangible and intangible benefits. Only one of the three High Court decisions delivered in this period used the term “intangible”.

&RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @ 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW

> @ > @ > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @

7HDP7DON DW > @ > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @

$PFRU DW > @ $V GLVFXVVHG LQ 6HFWLRQ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ PD\ KDYH EHHQ XVLQJ WKH WHUP

´WDQJLEOHµ LQ D GLIIHUHQFH VHQVH WR KRZ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ QRZ XVHV LW

1= 'DLU\ DW > @

&RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @

0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ 3RZHUFR DW

> @ > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 2PY DW

> @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ DQG 3RZHUFR DW > @ > @ GLG QRW XVH WKH WHUP ´LQWDQJLEOHµ LQVWHDG GHVFULELQJ VRPH EHQHILWV DV ´OHVV WDQJLEOH EHQHILWVµ

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW

Ł.2 Possible definitions

Ł.2.Ł AN ABSTRACT BENEFIT

The traditional notion of an intangible benefit is something that is “unable to be touched”. In the context of the public benefit test that would render all benefits intangibles, and so would not provide any distinction between benefits.

Ł.2.2 A BENEFIT THAT IS DIFFICULT TO QUANTIFY

An intangible benefit may be “something that cannot be precisely measured or assessed” in a particular unit of measurement. An inability to quantify benefits in a common unit of measurement makes it difficult to weigh benefits and detriments. Whilst the obvious unit of measurement for benefits is money, this is not the only unit of measurement. Benefits could be measured in other units, such as human utility or the percentage increase in productivity.

Because the public benefit test involves looking into the future and judging the level of benefit that would arise if an anti-competitive practice or acquisition was allowed to proceed, no benefit is capable of precise measurement or assessment. However, some benefits are easier to measure than others. It is this ease of measurement concept that provides the foundation for this definition of intangible benefits. The task of classifying benefits as tangibles and intangibles involves constructing a notional line of ease of quantification and placing the various benefits on the line. The final designation of a benefit as tangible or intangible depends upon where it lies in relation to a certain point separating tangibles from intangibles; if it is to the left of that point it is tangible and if it is to the right it is intangible. Figure 1 on the next page illustrates the classification process. Whilst it is easy to classify benefits at either end of the scale as tangible or intangible, the distinction is not so clear for benefits that lie in the middle of the scale.

7KH &RQFLVH 2[IRUG 'LFWLRQDU\ WK HG 2[IRUG 8QLYHUVLW\ 3UHVV 1HZ <RUN DW 7KLV LV KRZ WKH DFFRXQWLQJ SURIHVVLRQ YLHZV LQWDQJLEOH DVVHWV VHH &UDLJ 'HHJDQ DQG *UDQW 6DPNLQ 1HZ

=HDODQG )LQDQFLDO $FFRXQWLQJ UG HG 0F*UDZ +LOO %RRN &RPSDQ\ 0HOERXUQH DW

)RU H[DPSOH LW LV LPSRVVLEOH WR WRXFK D FRVW VDYLQJ DQ LQFUHDVH LQ H[SRUWV RU DQ HQYLURQPHQWDO EHQHILW

7KH &RQFLVH 2[IRUG 'LFWLRQDU\ DW

,Q IDFW LW LV RIWHQ HYHQ GLIILFXOW WR GHWHUPLQH ZKHUH D SDUWLFXODU EHQHILW OLHV RQ WKH VSHFWUXP RI WDQJLELOLW\ LQ UHODWLRQ WR DQRWKHU EHQHILW ,Q RWKHU ZRUGV LW FDQQRW EH VDLG GHILQLWLYHO\ WKDW WKH EHQHILW LV PRUH RU OHVV LQWDQJLEOH WKDQ WKH RWKHU EHQHILW

6

An illustration of the implicit classification of public benefits as tangibles or intangibles using an ease of quantification test.

intangible

benefits

tangible

benefits
the dividing line between

tangibles and intangibles

... where does it lie?

relatively difficult

to quantify

relatively easy

to quantify
FIG UR E 1 : The spectrum of tangibility

2006_200.png

A definition based upon a benefit's ease of quantification can be applied in the individual case or more generally. A case-by-case application involves considering whether that particular benefit is easily quantified in that particular case. A more general application entails examining whether the benefit can usually be easily quantified. For example, a certain health benefit may be easily quantifiable in a particular case. Hence it would be tangible on an individual application, but intangible on a more general application because health benefits are usually difficult to quantify.

Ł.2.3 A NON-MARKET BENEFIT

The classification of benefits as tangible or intangible could depend upon whether they arise in a market. Intangible benefits would be those benefits that do not accrue in a market setting. For example, there is no market in which improvements in environmental quality and increases in pride and spirit can be bought and sold. By contrast, cost savings, improvements in product quality and tourism benefits all arise in markets and so would be classified as tangible benefits.

Ł.2.4 AN INDIRECT BENEFIT

The concept of tangibility could be defined by reference to the persons to whom the benefits accrue. A tangible benefit would be one accruing to the parties immediately affected by the proposed acquisition or anti-competitive practice, and an intangible benefit would be a benefit accruing to persons beyond the immediate parties. The immediate parties would normally be the producer(s) applying for authorisation and the consumers of the product or service.

In the context of an airline merger the tangible benefits would be those accruing to the two airlines proposing to merge and the airlines' passengers. The intangible benefits would be those that benefited people outside this group; for example noise reductions and environmental spin-offs from a reduction in the number of flights.

7KHUH LV D PDUNHW IRU WKH SURGXFW RU VHUYLFH RQ ZKLFK WKH FRVW VDYLQJV DUH PDGH IRU WKH SURGXFW LQ UHVSHFW RI ZKLFK WKH TXDOLW\ LPSURYHPHQW DULVHV DQG IRU WRXULVP

Ł.2.5 A NON-EFFICIENCY BENEFIT

Finally, intangible benefits could be non-efficiency benefits. Efficiency is traditionally defined in competition law as incorporating allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency. Thus an increase in the cost-effectiveness of production, an increased incentive for efficient investment in research and development and the production of a more socially optimal level of output, would amount to tangible benefits. All other benefits would be intangible.

The inclusion of allocative efficiency within the definition of efficiency means that almost all benefits would be classified as tangible benefits. An environmental benefit would be a tangible benefit if it internalised or alleviated a negative externality, because to the extent that it does this, society's resources are better allocated. The types of benefits that would be intangible in nature include those that increase pride and harmony in a society and those that improve a society's relations with another society.

7KH GUDIW $XVWUDOLDQ DXWKRULVDWLRQ JXLGHOLQHV GUDZ D GLVWLQFWLRQ EHWZHHQ HIILFLHQF\ DQG QRQ HIILFLHQF\ EHQHILWV $XVWUDOLDQ &RPSHWLWLRQ DQG &RQVXPHU &RPPLVVLRQ *XLGH WR $XWKRULVDWLRQ 'UDIW IRU &RPPHQW $XVWUDOLDQ &RPSHWLWLRQ DQG &RQVXPHU &RPPLVVLRQ &DQEHUUD DW 7KH IRUPHU DUH FDOOHG ´HFRQRPLF SXEOLF EHQHILWVµ DQG WKH ODWWHU DUH FDOOHG ´QRQ HFRQRPLF SXEOLF EHQHILWVµ

$OORFDWLYH HIILFLHQF\ LV DFKLHYHG ZKHUH VRFLHW\·V UHVRXUFHV DUH DOORFDWHG WR WKH LQGLYLGXDOV WKDW YDOXH WKHP WKH PRVW SURGXFWLYH HIILFLHQF\ LV DFKLHYHG ZKHUH JRRGV DQG VHUYLFHV DUH SURGXFHG DW WKH ORZHVW FRVW DQG G\QDPLF HIILFLHQF\ LV DFKLHYHG ZKHUH WKH LQYHQWLRQ GHYHORSPHQW DQG GLIIXVLRQ RI QHZ SURGXFWV DQG SURGXFWLRQ SURFHVVHV LV HQFRXUDJHG VHH &RPPHUFH &OHDULQJ +RXVH 1HZ

=HDODQG %XVLQHVV /DZ *XLGH 9ROXPH &RPPHUFH &OHDULQJ +RXVH $XFNODQG DW

-RVHSK %URGOH\ ´7KH (FRQRPLFV *RDOV RI $QWLWUXVW (IILFLHQF\ &RQVXPHU :HOIDUH DQG 7HFKQRORJLFDO 3URJUHVVµ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

=HUEH DW

7KLV ZRXOG UHSUHVHQW DQ LQFUHDVH LQ SURGXFWLYH HIILFLHQF\

7KLV ZRXOG UHSUHVHQW DQ LQFUHDVH LQ G\QDPLF HIILFLHQF\

7KLV ZRXOG UHSUHVHQW DQ LQFUHDVH LQ DOORFDWLYH HIILFLHQF\

$ QHJDWLYH H[WHUQDOLW\ RFFXUV ZKHUH WKH DFWLRQ RI D ILUP RU LQGLYLGXDO FRQIHUV D FRVW RQ D WKLUG SDUW\ DQG QR FRPSHQVDWLRQ LV SDLG WR WKH WKLUG SDUW\ E\ WKH SDUW\ FRQIHUULQJ WKH FRVW VHH )UDQN DQG

%HUQDQNH DW 9DULDQ DW

Ł.3 Approach of the Commerce Commission

Ł.3.Ł GENERAL APPROACH

The Commission has adopted the definition in Section 1.2.2, equating the ease of measurement in monetary units with tangibility. This view was endorsed by the High Court in Rugby Union (HC). Hence an intangible benefit is one which is relatively difficult to quantify in monetary terms.

Such a definition is consistent with the history of usage of the term “intangible”. The commencement of its use coincided with the publication of the Guidelines to the Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments in the Context of the Commerce Act (“1994 Guidelines”) by the Commission, which described a tangible benefit as one that can be quantified in monetary units. This gives an indication of what the Commission meant when it used the term “intangible benefit” in the decisions that followed.

A definition based on quantifiability, is also in harmony with the Commission's more quantitative approach to the evaluation of public benefits since the Court of Appeal's decision in Telecom (CA). The Commission's decision in Ansett was the first time it extensively evaluated benefits and detriments in monetary terms and it was also one of the first times that the Commission drew a distinction between benefits based on their degree of tangibility. This implies that there may be a link between the Commission's notion of tangibility and the quantification of benefits.

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

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW

,QWHUHVWLQJO\ RQ WZR RFFDVLRQV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ KDV UHIHUUHG WR D EHQHILW DV EHLQJ RI DQ LQWDQJLEOH QDWXUH DQG WKHQ SURFHHGHG WR TXDQWLI\ LW 1=5)8 DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 7KLV LV HQWLUHO\ FRQVLVWHQW ZLWK WKH GHILQLWLRQ EHFDXVH LW KLQJHV XSRQ HDVH RI TXDQWLILFDWLRQ UDWKHU WKDQ TXDQWLILFDWLRQ SHU VH

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ *XLGHOLQHV WR WKH $QDO\VLV RI 3XEOLF %HQHILWV DQG 'HWULPHQWV LQ WKH &RQWH[W RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ :HOOLQJWRQ DW $ UHYLVHG YHUVLRQ RI WKHVH *XLGHOLQHV ZDV LVVXHG LQ

,Q 7HOHFRP &$ 5LFKDUGVRQ - VWUHVVHG WKH LPSRUWDQFH RI EHQHILWV DQG GHWULPHQWV EHLQJ PHDVXUHG LQ PRQHWDU\ WHUPV 7HOHFRP &$ DW 3ULRU WR WKLV TXDQWLILFDWLRQ RI EHQHILWV DQG GHWULPHQWV ZDV GRQH RQ D VSRUDGLF EDVLV ,W ZDV SUREDEO\ ODUJHO\ GHSHQGHQW RQ WKH HIIRUWV RI WKH DSSOLFDQWV WR SURYLGH TXDQWLILFDWLRQV LQ WKHLU DSSOLFDWLRQV

Defining intangibility by reference to ease of quantification is also consistent with the current Guidelines to the Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments (the “Guidelines”), which state that an intangible benefit “typically” cannot be readily measured in monetary terms. Although the Guidelines are not law and do not bind the Commission, the Commission usually refers to the Guidelines as setting out the principles used by the Commission in evaluating benefits, when applying the public benefit test. However, because the Commerce Act was amended in 2001 and the Guidelines have not been revised, their present status is uncertain. None of the changes directly impact upon the tangible and intangible benefit distinction, suggesting that the term “intangible benefit” still retains the same meaning as it bore in 1997. In any event, the Commission has indicated in its two most recent decisions that the economic principles used in assessing benefits and detriments remain unchanged.

It is not entirely clear whether when the Commission and courts refer to a benefit as being intangible, they are referring to it being difficult to quantify in the individual

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ *XLGHOLQHV WR WKH $QDO\VLV RI 3XEOLF %HQHILWV DQG 'HWULPHQWV &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ :HOOLQJWRQ DW 1RWH WKDW WKLV GHILQLWLRQ DSSHDUV WR EH VOLJKWO\ GLIIHUHQW WKDQ WKH RQH DGRSWHG LQ WKH *XLGHOLQHV :KLOVW WKH *XLGHOLQHV IRFXV XSRQ D EHQHILW·V HDVH RI TXDQWLILFDWLRQ WKH *XLGHOLQHV HTXDWH WDQJLELOLW\ ZLWK DELOLW\ WR TXDQWLI\ SHU VH VHH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW +HQFH WKH QRWLRQ RI DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW PD\ KDYH HYROYHG WR UHFRJQLVH WKDW D GHILQLWLRQ EDVHG XSRQ ZKHWKHU D EHQHILW FDQ EH TXDQWLILHG RYHU VLPSOLILHV WKH PDWWHU EHFDXVH DOO EHQHILWV FDQ EH TXDQWLILHG LI HQRXJK DVVXPSWLRQV DUH PDGH

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 3RZHUFR DW

> @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ $V 6WHSKHQ *DOH QRWHV ZKHWKHU WKH *XLGHOLQHV GR LQ IDFW UHSUHVHQW WKH ODZ UHPDLQV XQWHVWHG LQ KLJKHU FRXUWV 6WHSKHQ

*DOH 3LHFHV RI 6WULQJ 4XDQWLILFDWLRQ DQG WKH &RPPHUFH $FW 3DSHU SUHVHQWHG DW WKH WK $QQXDO

:RUNVKRS RI WKH &RPSHWLWLRQ DQG 3ROLF\ ,QVWLWXWH RI 1HZ =HDODQG :HOOLQJWRQ $XJXVW DW

,W KDV EHHQ VXJJHVWHG WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ ZLWKGUHZ WKH *XLGHOLQHV DIWHU WKH

$PHQGPHQWV /HJDO 6HUYLFHV $JHQF\ /DZ $FFHVV &DWDORJXH WK HG /HJDO 6HUYLFHV $JHQF\

DW &RPPHUFH &OHDULQJ +RXVH DW +RZHYHU 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG VWDWHV WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V YLHZ LV WKDW WKH *XLGHOLQHV KDYH QRW EHHQ ZLWKGUDZQ (PDLO IURP 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG WR -LOO &DXJKH\ 6HSWHPEHU RQ ILOH ZLWK DXWKRU 7KH\ DUH VWLOO DYDLODEOH RQ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V ZHEVLWH DW KWWS ZZZ FRPFRP JRYW Q] SXEOLFDWLRQV $UFKLYHG3XEOLFDWLRQV RWKHUSXEOLFDWLRQV DVS[ *LYHQ WKDW LW KDV EHHQ ILYH \HDUV VLQFH WKH $PHQGPHQW LW ORRNV XQOLNHO\ WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ ZLOO LVVXH D UHYLVHG YHUVLRQ LQ UHVSRQVH WR WKH $PHQGPHQW SURYLGLQJ IXUWKHU FRQILUPDWLRQ WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ FRQVLGHUV WKH *XLGHOLQHV WR UHSUHVHQW WKH ODZ

7KHUH ZHUH WKUHH PDLQ FKDQJHV 7KH ORQJ WLWOH WR WKH $FW ZDV UHSHDOHG DQG D QHZ SXUSRVH VHFWLRQ ZDV LQVHUWHG LQ V $ :KLOVW WKH REMHFWLYH RI WKH $FW LV VWLOO WR SURPRWH FRPSHWLWLRQ LQ PDUNHWV LQ 1HZ

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´7KH

*RDOV RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FWµ LQ 0DUN %HUU\ DQG /HZLV (YDQV HGV &RPSHWLWLRQ /DZ DW WKH 7XUQ RI WKH &HQWXU\ $ 1HZ =HDODQG 3HUVSHFWLYH 9LFWRULD 8QLYHUVLW\ 3UHVV :HOOLQJWRQ DW

4DQWDV DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG VXSSRUWV WKLV SRVLWLRQ (PDLO IURP 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG WR -LOO &DXJKH\ 6HSWHPEHU

case or it being generally difficult to quantify. The Guidelines seem to support a global approach to the classification of a benefit as an intangible. Guideline Four of the Guidelines describes an intangible benefit as a benefit “which typically cannot readily be measured in monetary terms”. This implies that even if a particular benefit can be readily measured in monetary terms in a given case, it will still be described as an intangible if it is usually difficult to measure in monetary terms. The global classification of intangibles will be adopted in the rest of this dissertation, because otherwise the analysis tends to collapse into a comparison of quantified and unquantified benefits.

Ł.3.2 BENEFITS THAT HAVE BEEN DESCRIBED AS INTANGIBLE BENEFITS

In their decisions the Commission and High Court have classified 12 benefits as intangible benefits:

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW HPSKDVLV DGGHG

, VD\ WHQGV WR EHFDXVH LW LV SRVVLEOH WKDW D EHQHILW WKDW LV SDUWLFXODUO\ GLIILFXOW WR TXDQWLI\ LQ WKH LQGLYLGXDO FDVH PD\ VWLOO EH TXDQWLILHG

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW $QVHWW DW > @ > @ PD\ DOVR KDYH UHIHUUHG WR WRXULVP DV FRQVWLWXWLQJ D OHVV WDQJLEOH EHQHILW

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW

5XDSHKX DW > @

,ELG DW > @

7HDP7DON DW > @ > @

3RZHUFR DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @

5XDSHKX DW > @

1=5)8 DW > @ 5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW 1=5)8 DW > @

1= 'DLU\ DW > @ ,Q WKDW FDVH WKH DYRLGDQFH RI FRPPXQLW\ GLVKDUPRQ\ ZDV FKDUDFWHULVHG E\ WKH DSSOLFDQW DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ GLG QRW GLVSXWH WKDW FKDUDFWHULVDWLRQ 7KH FODVVLILFDWLRQ RI FRPPXQLW\ KDUPRQ\ DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW LV VXSSRUWHG E\ WKH &KLHI (FRQRPLVW RI WKH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG ´7KH (YDOXDWLRQ RI 3XEOLF %HQHILW DQG 'HWULPHQW XQGHU WKH &RPPHUFH $FW µ 1HZ =HDODQG (FRQRPLF 3DSHUV DW

The Guidelines describe two further benefits as intangibles:

Ł.3.3 BENEFITS THAT HAVE BEEN DESCRIBED AS TANGIBLE BENEFITS

By contrast, it is useful to consider any benefits that the Commission has classified as being of a tangible nature. In Ansett it clearly made reference to two benefits as being tangible benefits:

Whilst the Commission described certain benefits as being tangible in its decision in Amcor in 1987, it is uncertain whether it was using the term in the same sense as it has been used more recently. The context suggests that the Commission may have been using tangible as a synonym for real or significant.

Where the Commission and courts have used the term “intangible benefit” in decisions, they have done so rather loosely. For example, in NZRFU 2 spectator enjoyment was referred to as being of an intangible nature, but no reference was made to the “feel-good” factor accruing to New Zealanders from improved international performances being an intangible benefit. The latter is almost

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW

4DQWDV DW > @

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW DQG

,ELG DW DQG

$QVHWW DW > @

,ELG

$PFRU DW > @ 7KHVH EHQHILWV LQFOXGHG LQFUHDVHG HPSOR\PHQW H[SRUW HDUQLQJV DQG VSLQ RII HIIHFWV WR WKH ORFDO 1RUWKODQG HFRQRP\

*LYHQ WKDW WKH *XLGHOLQHV ZHUH QRW SXEOLVKHG XQWLO VHYHQ \HDUV DIWHU WKH GHFLVLRQ ZDV GHOLYHUHG WKH &RPPLVVLRQ FDQQRW KDYH EHHQ PDNLQJ LPSOLFLW UHIHUHQFH WR WKH *XLGHOLQHV· GHILQLWLRQ RI D WDQJLEOH EHQHILW DV RQH ZKLFK FDQ EH TXDQWLILHG LQ PRQHWDU\ WHUPV

$PFRU DW > @ 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ VWDWHG WKDW WKH ´«SURMHFW ZRXOG SURYLGH WDQJLEOH SXEOLF EHQHILWV LQ WHUPV RI «µ

certainly more intangible than the former. This looseness in expression means that it cannot automatically be inferred that all benefits in these decisions that are not described as intangible benefits are tangible benefits. However, in TeamTalk and Ruapehu the Commission discussed the various intangible benefits under a heading “intangible benefits”. In such circumstances it can sensibly be inferred that the Commission must have considered the other benefits to be tangible benefits. These benefits included:
The Guidelines support the classification of cost savings and net revenue increases as tangibles.

Ł.3.4 CONSISTENCY OF THE COMMISSION'S APPROACH

The limited number of decisions describing benefits as intangibles, the irregular use of the term by the Commission and the lack of description of other benefits as tangibles, make it difficult to analyse whether the Commission has been consistent in its classification of benefits as intangibles. The best that can be hoped for is a critique of the Commission's categorisation decisions based on what little we can glean from the decisions, the basic principles set out in the Guidelines and a dash of common sense.

The classification of tourism as an intangible benefit in Rugby Union (HC) is at odds with the implicit classification of it as a tangible benefit in the Ruapehu decision.

1=5)8 DW > @ 7KLV ORRVHQHVV LQ H[SUHVVLRQ FDQ SUREDEO\ EH H[SODLQHG E\ WKH IDFW WKDW QRWKLQJ WXUQV RQ WKH FODVVLILFDWLRQ DOO EHQHILWV DUH FRQVLGHUHG UHJDUGOHVV RI ZKHWKHU WKH\ DUH LQWDQJLEOH RU WDQJLEOH

7HDP7DON DW > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ ,Q 3RZHUFR DW > @ > @ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ GLVFXVVHG FHUWDLQ EHQHILWV XQGHU D KHDGLQJ ´RWKHU OHVV WDQJLEOH EHQHILWVµ ,W LV XQFHUWDLQ ZKHWKHU WKLV ZDV PHDQW WR HQFRPSDVV DOO LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV ,I LW ZDV FRVW VDYLQJV DYRLGHG VRFLDO FRVWV RI XQHPSOR\PHQW DQG UHGXFHG RXWDJH FRVWV IRU FRQVXPHUV ZRXOG DOO DPRXQW WR WDQJLEOH EHQHILWV 7KH VHFRQG VHHPV SDUWLFXODUO\ GLIILFXOW WR TXDQWLI\ ZKLFK VXJJHVWV WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ PD\ KDYH VLPSO\ XVHG WKH KHDGLQJ ´RWKHU OHVV WDQJLEOH EHQHILWVµ DV D V\QRQ\P IRU XQTXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV

7HDP7DON 5XDSHKX 7KLV VXSSRUWV WKH FODVVLILFDWLRQ LQ $QVHWW DW > @

7HDP7DON 5XDSHKX 7KLV VXSSRUWV WKH FODVVLILFDWLRQ LQ $QVHWW DW > @

5XDSHKX 7KLV LV DW RGGV ZLWK WKH FODVVLILFDWLRQ RI WRXULVP DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW LQ 5XJE\ 8QLRQ

+& DW )RU IXUWKHU GLVFXVVLRQ DERXW WKLV LQFRQVLVWHQF\ VHH 6HFWLRQ EHORZ

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ $V GLVFXVVHG LQ 6HFWLRQ E\ GLVFXVVLQJ WKH YDULRXV LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV XQGHU D KHDGLQJ ´LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWVµ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQ 5XDSHKX LPSOLHG WKDW DOO WKH RWKHU EHQHILWV ZHUH WDQJLEOH EHQHILWV 2QH RI WKHVH RWKHU EHQHILWV ZDV WKH

Closer examination of Rugby Union (HC) suggests that the High Court may have been using the term “intangible” loosely. After describing a number of benefits, including increased tourism as intangible, the Court appeared to partially contradict itself in the following sentence by stating that “some” of the benefits just mentioned could properly be described as intangibles. Therefore it is not certain that the High Court meant to describe tourism as an intangible benefit.

Interestingly, in the Ruapehu decision the Commission described the development and transfer of expertise between two ski-fields as an intangible benefit. This is inconsistent with the Guidelines’ classification of benefits deriving from economies of scale and scope, and cost reductions due to greater specialisation of production, as tangibles. The Commission may have been using the word “intangible” as a synonym for unquantified benefits.

These inconsistencies demonstrate the difficulty of ascertaining the features that make a particular benefit an intangible one. This issue is explored further in the next section.

Ł.4 The common features of intangible benefits

As discussed in Section 1.2.2, an ease of quantification definition gives rise to difficulties classifying benefits as tangible or intangible. This problem is particularly acute for benefits lying in the middle of the “spectrum of intangibility”. The Commission has not developed any test or indicators to assist in this classification process. This section aims to analyse the features of intangible benefits in search of developing a workable framework within which to evaluate their treatment.

LQFUHDVHG WRXULVP VSHQGLQJ WKDW ZRXOG DFFUXH WR WKH 5RWRUXD UHJLRQ DV D UHVXOW RI WKH DFTXLVLWLRQ RI 7XURD 6NL 5HVRUW E\ 5XDSHKX $OSLQH /LIWV

5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW

,W PD\ KDYH EHHQ XVLQJ WKH LQWDQJLELOLW\ WDJ EHFDXVH RI WKH ZHDN QH[XV EHWZHHQ WKH WRXULVP EHQHILWV DQG WKH WUDQVIHU V\VWHP VHHNLQJ WR EH DXWKRULVHG UDWKHU WKDQ DQ\ LQKHUHQW LQDELOLW\ WR TXDQWLI\ EHQHILWV IURP LQFUHDVHG WRXULVP ,Q RWKHU ZRUGV LW PD\ KDYH DSSOLHG DQ HDVH RI TXDQWLILFDWLRQ WHVW LQ WKH LQGLYLGXDO FDVH UDWKHU WKDQ LQ WKH JOREDO VHQVH

5XDSHKX DW > @

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

$OO WKH EHQHILWV GHVFULEHG DV WDQJLEOH EHQHILWV ZHUH TXDQWLILHG DQG DOO WKH EHQHILWV GHVFULEHG DV LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV ZHUH XQTXDQWLILHG

7KH FODVVLILFDWLRQ RI RWKHU EHQHILWV DV LQWDQJLEOH LV TXHVWLRQDEOH )RU H[DPSOH VHH 5XJE\ 8QLRQ

+& DW LQ SDUWLFXODU ,Q WKDW FDVH WKH +LJK &RXUW FLWHG SRWHQWLDOO\ LPSURYHG VSRQVRUVKLS DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW $OWKRXJK WKHUH LV QRWKLQJ LQ WKH GHFLVLRQV RU WKH *XLGHOLQHV WR VXJJHVW WKDW LW VKRXOG QRW EH FODVVLILHG DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW LW VHHPV TXLWH GLIIHUHQW LQ QDWXUH WR PDQ\ RI WKH RWKHU EHQHILWV WKDW DUH FODVVLILHG DV LQWDQJLEOH

Dr Michael Pickford, the Chief Economist of the Commerce Commission, suggests that intangible benefits usually share two characteristic features which mean that quantification is generally not a realistic possibility. The first is that are difficult to describe precisely. He may be alluding to the fact that these benefits often arise indirectly through a number of channels, making their existence doubtful and their nature difficult to characterise. For this reason, claims of intangible benefits are often quite speculative. Because it is difficult to prove their existence, let alone their extent, quantification is problematic.

The second feature that Pickford suggests intangible benefits usually share is that there is no obvious economic framework through which their value can be assessed. This makes sense. Because intangibles are benefits that are difficult to quantify, it is likely that there will be no obvious economic model in which to assess their value. In considering whether such a framework exists, it is useful to examine the unit of measurement that the benefit is ordinarily measured in. As a rough guideline, if the natural unit to measure the benefit in is in dollar terms it is a tangible benefit, and if it is something else it is an intangible benefit. Applying this rule, cost savings are tangible benefits because their natural unit of measurement is in dollars, and health benefits are intangible benefits because their natural unit of measurement is improvements in mortality and morbidity rates.

Another useful consideration is whether the benefit is a productive efficiency gain. The examples of tangible benefits in the Guidelines are all productive efficiency gains that result in cost savings or net revenue gains. It is generally much easier for person(s) to quantify cost savings or net revenue gains, than to quantify the more amorphous and far reaching allocative and dynamic efficiency gains. Hence productive efficiency gains tend to be tangible benefits, and non-productive efficiency gains tend to be intangible benefits.

0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG 7KH (YDOXDWLRQ RI 3XEOLF %HQHILW DQG 'HWULPHQW XQGHU WKH &RPPHUFH $FW

2FFDVLRQDO 3DSHU 1R &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ :HOOLQJWRQ DW 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ SLFNHG XS RQ WKHVH WZR IDFWRUV LQ $QVHWW DW > @ LQ UHODWLRQ WR LPSURYHG GLSORPDWLF UHODWLRQV

3LFNIRUG DW

7KLV ZDV RQH RI WKH WKUHH UHDVRQV ZK\ WKH EHQHILWV LQ 1=5)8 ZHUH VR LQWULQVLFDOO\ GLIILFXOW WR PHDVXUH 7KH RWKHU WZR UHDVRQV LQFOXGHG WKH IDFW WKDW WKH\ ZRXOG EH GHULYHG LQ D PDUNHW LQ ZKLFK FRPPHUFLDO WUDQVDFWLRQV KDG QRW \HW RFFXUUHG DQG WKDW WKH\ ZRXOG IORZ IURP YHU\ PLOG PDUNHW UHJXODWLRQV 1=5)8 DW > @

3LFNIRUG DW

*XLGHOLQH RI WKH *XLGHOLQHV &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW 6HH DOVR &RPPHUFH

&RPPLVVLRQ DW

$ULVLQJ IURP WKH EHWWHU XWLOLVDWLRQ RI UHVRXUFHV DQG HFRQRPLHV RI VFDOH

,W LV HYHQ PRUH GLIILFXOW WR TXDQWLI\ QRQ HIILFLHQF\ JDLQV

Ł.5 The approach utilised in this dissertation: a spectrum of tangibility

There will be some benefits for which it is not possible to predict whether the Commission would classify them as tangible or intangible. In the end this does not matter. The treatment of intangible benefits can be evaluated by constructing a “spectrum of tangibility”; with very tangible benefits at one end, very intangible benefits at the other end and intermediate benefits in the middle. Such a spectrum is consistent with how the Commission views the quantification of detriments. In the Guidelines, the Commission recognises that quantifiability is a continuum and not all detriments are equally capable of quantification. This same reasoning can be applied to benefits. By considering how the Commission treats benefits of varying levels of tangibility, we can gain an insight into how the Commission treats the so-called intangible benefits and also see whether the treatment of intangibles of varying levels of tangibility differs.

There is no easy way to place benefits on the spectrum of tangibility. It essentially involves a value judgment. It is proposed that the benefits, other than the classic tangible benefits, such as cost savings and net revenue increases, can be grouped into four main categories to help reduce the complexity of the value judgments that need to be made. These are set out on the next page in Table 1, and their scope and characteristics are discussed in more detail below.

6HH )LJXUH LQ 6HFWLRQ :KLOVW 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG EHOLHYHV WKDW UDWKHU WKDQ WKHUH EHLQJ D

´VSHFWUXP RI WDQJLELOLW\µ RI EHQHILWV WKHUH LV D ´GLFKRWRP\µ EHWZHHQ WKH WDQJLEOH DQG LQWDQJLEOH KH DFNQRZOHGJHV WKDW IRU WKH LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV WKHUH PD\ EH GHJUHHV RI LQWDQJLELOLW\ (PDLO IURP 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG WR -LOO &DXJKH\ $XJXVW

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

7KHUH DUH RWKHU EHQHILWV WKDW PD\ ZHOO EH LQWDQJLEOH EXW GR QRW IDOO LQWR WKHVH FDWHJRULHV ,W LV SURSRVHG WKDW WKLV GLVVHUWDWLRQ ZLOO QRW FRQVLGHU WKHLU WUHDWPHQW ,QVWHDG LW ZLOO FRQFHQWUDWH RQ IXOO\ HYDOXDWLQJ WKH IRXU EDVLF FDWHJRULHV RXWOLQHG LQ WKH WDEOH RQ WKH QH[W SDJH

TABLE Ł: Categories of benefits
Sub- category
Category Ł:
Category 2:
Category 3:
Category 4:
vague claims with far reaching consequences
externality arguments
quality improvements
improving New Zealand's export performance
A
“feel-good” benefits
environmental benefits
increased quality and choice for consumers
tourism benefits
B
promoting New
Zealand's general interests at an international level
health benefits
improved information in the marketplace
enhanced export opportunities
C

social benefits
improvements in bargaining relationships
improvements in international competitiveness

Ł.5.Ł CATEGORY Ł: VAGUE CLAIMS WITH FAR REACHING CONSEQUENCES

This category represents the benefits that are the least easily quantified. The common feature that underpins them is that they are all benefits that affect a large group of people but only very marginally. Hence, they usually arise very indirectly and it is virtually impossible to devise an economic model that assesses their impact with any accuracy. There are two sub-categories within this category: the “feel-good” benefits, and benefits promoting New Zealand's general interests at an international level. The latter benefits may be slightly more tangible than the former.

Because of the amorphous nature of this category, it is illustrative to provide a list of the benefits that have been raised in decisions that would fall within each of the sub-categories. The “feel-good” benefit sub-category incorporates:

7KHVH DUH WKH YHU\ WZR IHDWXUHV WKDW 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG LGHQWLILHG DV XVXDOO\ EHLQJ VKDUHG E\ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV 3LFNIRUG DW

&DWHJRU\ $

7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ 1=5)8 DW > @ 7KH IHHO JRRG IDFWRU ZDV VDLG WR DULVH IURP WKH EHWWHU SHUIRUPDQFH RI LQWHUQDWLRQDO UXJE\ VTXDGV

'HVFULEHG DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW LQ 4DQWDV DW > @ ,W ZDV DOVR FODLPHG LQ $QVHWW DW > @

> @

The benefits falling within the second sub-category, as promoting New Zealand's general interests at an international level, include:

Ł.5.2 CATEGORY 2: EXTERNALITY ARGUMENTS

These benefits also accrue to the broader community. Benefits within this category tend to partially or fully internalise negative externalities. Although these benefits are generally easier to quantify than the preceding category, quantification is still problematic because they represent improvements in social rather than economic outcomes. There are three basic sub-categories: environmental benefits, health benefits and social benefits. Whilst none of these benefits have been described as intangibles in the decisions, the first two sub-categories are described as intangible benefits in the Guidelines.

'HVFULEHG DV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW E\ WKH DSSOLFDQW LQ 1= 'DLU\ DW > @ ,W ZDV DOVR FODLPHG LQ

.LZL DW > @ DOWKRXJK QR VSHFLILF UHIHUHQFH ZDV PDGH WR LW EHLQJ RI DQ LQWDQJLEOH QDWXUH

7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ .LZLIUXLW DW > @

7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @

&DWHJRU\ %

7KH &RPPLVVLRQ PD\ KDYH LPSOLHG WKLV ZDV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW LQ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ $W

> @ LW VWDWHG WKDW LW ZDV GLIILFXOW WR VD\ H[DFWO\ ZKDW WKH QDWXUH RI WKLV EHQHILW ZDV DQG KRZ LW FRXOG EH HYDOXDWHG 7KHVH DUH WKH WZR IDFWRUV WKDW 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG LGHQWLILHV DV EHLQJ VKDUHG E\ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV 3LFNIRUG DW

7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ $PFRU DW > @ 1= 'DLU\ DW > @

7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ 4DQWDV DW > @

,Q RWKHU ZRUGV WKH\ DOOHYLDWH WKH QHJDWLYH VSLQ RII LQ WKH SUH DFTXLVLWLRQ RU SUH DQWLFRPSHWLWLYH SUDFWLFH VLWXDWLRQ )RU DQ H[SODQDWLRQ RI ZKDW D QHJDWLYH H[WHUQDOLW\ LV VHH DERYH IRRWQRWH

&DWHJRU\ $ 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ > @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW

> @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @

&DWHJRU\ % $ KHDWK EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ > @ 3XEOLF VDIHW\ EHQHILWV IDOO ZLWKLQ WKH KHDOWK FDWHJRU\ 6XFK EHQHILWV KDYH EHHQ UDLVHG LQ IRXU GHFLVLRQV 6HH

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ 1DWXUDO *DV :DLNDWR DW > @ 6SHHGZD\ DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW

> @

&DWHJRU\ & 7KLV VXE FDWHJRU\ IRFXVHV XSRQ WKH EURDGHU FRVWV WR WKH FRPPXQLW\ RI XQHPSOR\PHQW DQG GHFUHDVHG SURGXFWLRQ ,W GRHV QRW LQFRUSRUDWH WKH PXOWLSOLHU HIIHFWV RI DQ LQFUHDVH LQ RXWSXW 1RU GRHV LW ORRN DW LQFUHDVHG HPSOR\PHQW SHU VH %HQHILWV IDOOLQJ ZLWKLQ &DWHJRU\ & KDYH EHHQ GLVFXVVHG LQ :KDNDWX DW > @ > @ $PFRU DW > @ )OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW

> @ 7DVPDQ DW > @ *UDSH *URZHUV DW > @ > @ &RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @ 3RZHUFR DW

> @ > @ 1RWH WKDW WKHUH PD\ ZHOO EH EHQHILWV WKDW IDOO ZLWKLQ &DWHJRU\ EXW IDOO RXWVLGH WKH WKUHH VXE FDWHJRULHV )RU H[DPSOH VHH 5DYHVGRZQ DW > @ > @ ,Q WKDW GHFLVLRQ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQGLFDWHG WKDW D EHQHILW WR RWKHU WUDQVSRUW XVHUV IURP UHGXFHG URDG XVDJH FRXOG EH D SXEOLF EHQHILW

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

Ł.5.3 CATEGORY 3: QUALITY IMPROVEMENTS

These benefits are more tangible in nature. Unlike the former categories, they arise in a market and generally accrue to the immediate parties in the market(s) concerned, making it easier to demonstrate the benefit's existence. However, because they each concern a quality improvement, their natural unit of measurement is not in dollar terms and so it is difficult to find a framework within which to accurately assess their value. There are three sub-categories: increased quality and choice for consumers, improved information in the marketplace and improvements in bargaining relationships. The Commission and High Court have described benefits falling within the first sub-category as intangibles in six of the eight decisions that label benefits as intangible.

Ł.5.4 CATEGORY 4: IMPROVING NEW ZEALAND'S EXPORT PERFORMANCE

These benefits are the most tangible of the four categories. They all relate to improvements in New Zealand's export performance. There are three sub- categories: tourism benefits, enhanced export opportunities and improvements in international competitiveness. There is much overlap between

:KHWKHU LW EH LQ UHODWLRQ WR D SURGXFW RU VHUYLFH WKH LQIRUPDWLRQ LQ D PDUNHWSODFH RU WKH QHJRWLDWLQJ HQYLURQPHQW

&DWHJRU\ $ 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ 9HJHWDEOH *URZHUV DW > @ $PFRU DW > @ 1DWXUDO

*DV :DLNDWR DW > @ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ > @ )LVKHU 3D\NHO DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 1=6(

DW > @ 1=6( DW > @ > @ 6SHHGZD\ DW > @ > @ 7HOHFRP &$ DW 6)( DW > @ > @

> @ > @ > @ 6)( DW > @ > @ > @ > @ > @ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ > @ 3RZHUFR DW > @ > @ > @ 7UDQVSRZHU DW > @ > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @

1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @

> @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @

&DWHJRU\ % 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ /LIH 8QGHUZULWHUV DW > @ *UDSH *URZHUV DW > @ (OHFWULFLW\ &RUSRUDWLRQ DW > @ (OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW > @ > @

&DWHJRU\ & 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ %ULHUOH\ DW > @ > @ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ *UDSH

*URZHUV DW > @ (QHUFR DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ ,Q IDFW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ KDV DFNQRZOHGJHG WKDW E\ LWV YHU\ QDWXUH LQFUHDVHG EDUJDLQLQJ SRZHU LV XQDEOH WR EH SUHFLVHO\ PHDVXUHG (QHUFR DW

> @

1=5)8 DW > @ 5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW 3RZHUFR DW > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 7KH FODVVLILFDWLRQ RI VXFK EHQHILWV DV LQWDQJLEOH PD\ EH LQFRQVLVWHQW ZLWK KRZ WKH &KLHI (FRQRPLVW RI WKH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG YLHZV WKHP ,Q WZR RI KLV SXEOLFDWLRQV KH JDYH HQKDQFHG FRQVXPHU VXUSOXV D VHSDUDWH KHDGLQJ IURP LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV ZKLFK PD\ LQGLFDWH KH FRQVLGHUV TXDOLW\ LPSURYHPHQWV QRW WR EH LQWDQJLEOH LQ QDWXUH

3LFNIRUG DW 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG ´$VVHVVLQJ 3XEOLF %HQHILWV DQG 'HWULPHQWVµ

&RPSOLDQFH DW

&DWHJRU\ $ 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ $QVHWW DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @

> @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @

&DWHJRU\ % 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU DW > @ $PFRU DW > @ > @

> @ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @

&DWHJRU\ & 7KLV EHQHILW ZDV GLVFXVVHG LQ )RUHVW 3URGXFWV DW > @ :KDNDWX DW > @ $PFRU DW

> @ )OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ 7DVPDQ DW > @ &DUWHU +ROW DW > @ 1= 'DLU\ DW > @

enhanced export opportunities and improvements in international competitiveness. Nevertheless, because the latter sub-category seems less tangible, the benefit has been divided into two sub-categories in order to evaluate whether the framing of the benefit makes a difference to the Commission's treatment of it.

It is unclear whether the Commission sees these benefits as tangible or intangible benefits. There is authority suggesting that tourism is an intangible benefit and authority suggesting it is a tangible benefit. Unlike the other three categories, the natural unit of measurement of Category 4 benefits is in monetary terms, suggesting that they are more likely to be tangible benefits.

Ł.5.5 OTHER BENEFITS

There are a number of benefits that could potentially be described as intangibles, but that do not fit neatly into any of the categories above. They include:

> @ 1= 'DLU\ +& DW LZL DW > @ &RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 4DQWDV

+& DW > @

1= 'DLU\ DW > @ VKRZV WKH LQWHUUHODWLRQVKLS EHWZHHQ HQKDQFHG H[SRUWV &DWHJRU\ % LPSURYHPHQWV LQ LQWHUQDWLRQDO FRPSHWLWLYHQHVV &DWHJRU\ & DQG DVVLVWLQJ 1HZ =HDODQG·V JHQHUDO LQWHUHVWV DW DQ LQWHUQDWLRQDO OHYHO &DWHJRU\ % ,Q WKDW FDVH WKH DSSOLFDQW VXEPLWWHG WKDW WKHUH ZRXOG EH LQFUHDVHG H[SRUWV RI D ZLGHU UDQJH RI YDOXH DGGHG SURGXFWV ZKLFK ZRXOG LQFUHDVH LQWHUQDWLRQDO FRPSHWLWLYHQHVV HQKDQFLQJ SURVSHFWV XQGHU WKH $XVWUDOLD 1HZ =HDODQG &ORVHU (FRQRPLF 5HODWLRQV &(5 7UDGH $JUHHPHQW LQ SDUWLFXODU ,Q WKH ILQDO GHFLVLRQ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ GLG QRW VHHP WR JLYH DQ\ ZHLJKWLQJ WR WKHVH EHQHILWV LQVWHDG IRFXVLQJ XSRQ RWKHU EHQHILWV 1= 'DLU\ DW

> @ > @

7KH OLQNV EHWZHHQ WKH VXE FDWHJRULHV LOOXVWUDWH WKH GLIILFXOW\ RI GHYHORSLQJ FODVVHV RI EHQHILWV EDVHG RQ WKH GHJUHH RI WDQJLELOLW\ RI EHQHILWV

6HH WKH GLVFXVVLRQ LQ 6HFWLRQ DERYH 5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW VXJJHVWV WKDW WRXULVP LV DQ LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILW EXW 5XDSHKX LPSOLHV LW LV D WDQJLEOH EHQHILW 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG VXJJHVWV WKDW EHFDXVH WKH &RPPLVVLRQ TXDQWLILHG WRXULVP EHQHILWV LQ 4DQWDV LW LV ´GLIILFXOW WR FODVVLI\ WKHVH DV EHLQJ LQWDQJLEOHµ (PDLO IURP 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG WR -LOO &DXJKH\ $XJXVW +RZHYHU DV GLVFXVVHG DERYH WKH WHVW RI LQWDQJLELOLW\ LV EDVHG XSRQ HDVH RI TXDQWLILFDWLRQ UDWKHU WKDQ TXDQWLILFDWLRQ SHU VH ,Q 1=5)8 DW > @ DQG 1=5)8 DW > @ VSHFWDWRU HQMR\PHQW ZDV UHIHUUHG WR DV EHLQJ LQWDQJLEOH GHVSLWH EHLQJ TXDQWLILHG

7KHLU QDWXUDO XQLW RI PHDVXUHPHQW LV LQ PRQHWDU\ WHUPV UDWKHU WKDQ H[SRUW YROXPHV EHFDXVH WKH GHVLUHG HQG UHVXOW LV DQ LQFUHDVH LQ H[SRUW UHFHLSWV QRW DQ LQFUHDVH LQ H[SRUW YROXPH 7KLV FDQ EH FRQWUDVWHG ZLWK HQYLURQPHQWDO VSLQ RIIV DQG TXDOLW\ LPSURYHPHQWV ZKLFK DUH LQ WKHPVHOYHV WKH GHVLUHG HQG UHVXOW

6XFK D YLHZ LV FRQVLVWHQW ZLWK 3LFNIRUG DW LQ ZKLFK 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG JDYH LQFUHDVHG SURILWV IURP H[SRUWV D VHSDUDWH KHDGLQJ IURP LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV VXJJHVWLQJ KH GRHV QRW FRQVLGHU WKHP WR EH LQWDQJLEOH LQ QDWXUH

6R WKHUH LV D ILIWK UHVLGXDO FDWHJRU\ RI EHQHILWV

5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @

4DQWDV DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @

This dissertation will not consider the treatment of this residual category of benefits. Their infrequent occurrence and the difficulty of placing them on the spectrum of tangibility, mean that further analysis is of little assistance to determining how intangible benefits are treated.

Ł.5.6 THE SPECTRUM OF TANGIBILITY

Figure 2 on the next page sets out the spectrum of tangibility which was first introduced in Section 1.2.2. The categories of benefits introduced above have been placed upon it. As discussed, there is no definitive test for determining the degree of tangibility of a particular benefit, and so the placement of such categories is essentially a value judgment. This spectrum will be used in Chapter Two to analyse the Commission and courts' treatment of intangible benefits.

(OHFWULFLW\ &RUSRUDWLRQ DW > @

(OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW > @

)LVKHU 3D\NHO DW > @ > @

%ULHUOH\ DW > @ 1RWH WKDW V RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW VWDWHV WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ VKDOO KDYH UHJDUG WR WKH HFRQRPLF SROLFLHV RI WKH JRYHUQPHQW DV FRPPXQLFDWHG E\ WKH 0LQLVWHU ZKHQ DSSO\LQJ WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW WHVW

4DQWDV DW > @

3HWUROHXP &RUSRUDWLRQ DW > @

1HZFDOO DW > @

2U HYHQ WKH UHODWLYH SRVLWLRQ RI D SDUWLFXODU EHQHILW

22

7 KH D X WK R U·V Y LH Z R I Z KH UH WKH IRX U FD WHJR ULHV R I E HQH ILWV XGWLLOQLV HWK LV G LVVH UWD WLR Q WR H YD OX D WH WK H WUH D WP H Q W R I LQ WD QJ LE OH E HQH OLH RQ WKH VS H FWUX P R I WD QJ LE LOLW\

LQ WD Q J LE OH

E HQH ILWV

WD QJ LE OH

E HQH ILWV
% $

&
%
$
&
$ %
&D WH JRU\ Q X P E H U

UH OD WLY H O\ G LIILFX OW

WR T X D Q WLI\

UH OD WLY H O\ H D V\

WR T X D Q WLI\
FIG UR E 2 : The categorisation approach to the spectrum of tangibility
% S UR P R WLQ J 1 HZ =H DOD Q G ·V LQ WH UH VWV

D W D Q LQ WH UQ D WLRQ DO OH YH O

$ ´IH H O J R R Gµ E H QH ILWV
H [ WH UQ D OLW\ D UJX P HQ WV
$ LQ FUH D VH G T X DOLW\ D Q G F K R LF H IR U

F RQ VX P H UV

% LP S UR YHGLQ IR UP D WLR Q LQ WK H P D UN H WS ODF H
& LP S UR YH P HQ WV LQ E D UJ D LQ LQ J

UH OD WLRQ VK LS V
. ( < $ WRX ULVP E H Q H ILWV

% HQK DQ FH G H [ S R UW R SS R UWXQ LWLH V

& LP SUR YH P HQ WV LQ LQ WH UQ D WLR Q D O F R P S H WLWLY H Q H VV

2006_201.png

C H AP T E R T W 0

The Treatment of Intangible Benefits

As discussed in the Introduction, the Commission and courts have taken a very broad approach to what amounts to a “public benefit”. Accordingly, all gains to the public of New Zealand, irrespective of their degree of tangibility, are “public benefits” and so must be assessed. The fact that a benefit cannot be readily expressed in monetary terms is no reason to exclude it from the balancing process. The Act provides no guidance as to how tangible and intangible benefits should be weighed; this is left to the Commission and courts.

The Commission and courts have emphasised the need for quantification of benefits and detriments where possible. Shelley Duggan suggests that this means that “intangible and social benefits will be considered irrelevant, or alternatively, will be given little weight in terms of the balancing exercise”. Even the Chief Economist of the Commerce Commission, Dr Michael Pickford, seems to agree, at least for the most part, with this view. Although Pickford recognises that intangible benefits must be included in the assessment, he suggests that “it is probably fair to say that, in the absence of quantification, the Commission will need some fairly convincing evidence that they will eventuate before much weight is given to them”. Nevertheless, unlike Duggan, Pickford does not entirely exclude the possibility that intangible benefits could be of real weight in a particular instance. He simply suggests that it will be a rare case where the applicant can discharge their burden of proving that the benefit will arise as a result of the practice, will not occur under the counterfactual and is of real magnitude.

This Chapter aims to evaluate the weight that the Commission and courts give to intangible benefits, to contrast the treatment of quantified intangibles and

1=5)8 DW > @ 5XJE\ 8QLRQ +& DW 7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 2PY DW

> @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @

4DQWDV +& DW > @

1DWXUDO *DV DW > @ 1HZFDOO DW > @ 7UDQVSRZHU DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 4DQWDV DW

> @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ 6HH DOVR &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW 7KLV PRUH TXDQWLWLDWYH DSSURDFK LV LQ UHVSRQVH WR WKH FRPPHQWV RI WKH &RXUW RI $SSHDO LQ 7HOHFRP &$ DW

6KHOO\ 'XJJDQ ´6SRUWLQJ (QWLWLHV DQG 7UDGH 3UDFWLFHV /DZ :KDW LV %HVW DQG )DLUHVW"µ 7UDGH 3UDFWLFHV /DZ -RXUQDO DW

3LFNIRUG DW

unquantified intangibles and to consider whether the treatment of intangibles has changed over time.

2. Ł Quantified intangibles

The Commission has quantified a number of benefits of an intangible nature in monetary terms, including: social benefits, increased quality and choice for consumers, better quality decision making and tourism benefits. The decisions indicate that the Commission takes a conservative approach to the quantification of intangible benefits. Because the economic models that are used to quantitatively evaluate intangible public benefit claims usually depend upon a series of simplifying assumptions, the calculations are often discounted to make due allowance for the difficulty of quantification. For example, in Qantas the Commission and High Court suggested that the value the Commission arrived at for the potential scheduling benefits was the upper limit. By contrast, the Commission had no such reservations in respect of the most tangible benefit, cost savings. Therefore, rather than using their best estimate of the intangible benefit that will arise, the Commission usually takes a more conservative figure as representing the value of the benefit. This more conservative approach means that, ceteris paribus, less weighting will usually be accorded to quantified intangible benefits than quantified tangible benefits.

3HUKDSV XQVXUSULVLQJO\ DOO RI WKHVH GHFLVLRQV FDPH DIWHU WKH &RXUW RI $SSHDO·V GHFLVLRQ LQ 7HOHFRP &$ LQ LQ ZKLFK 5LFKDUGVRQ - VWUHVVHG WKH GHVLUDELOLW\ RI TXDQWLI\LQJ EHQHILWV LQ

PRQHWDU\ WHUPV 7HOHFRP &$ DW

&DWHJRU\ & 6HH 3RZHUFR DW > @ > @ $OWKRXJK WKDW FDVH GHDOW ZLWK VRFLDO GHWULPHQWV DULVLQJ IURP UHGXQGDQF\ SUHVXPDEO\ WKH VDPH PHWKRGRORJ\ FDQ EH DSSOLHG WR VRFLDO EHQHILWV DULVLQJ IURP UHGXQGDQF\ :KLOVW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ VWDWHG WKDW LW ZDV QRW SRVVLEOH WR TXDQWLI\ WKH VL]H RI WKH RQH RII VRFLDO FRVWV IURP VWDII UHGXFWLRQV WKH\ FDPH XS ZLWK D EDOO SDUN ILJXUH WR GHPRQVWUDWH ´WKH LPSDFW WKH\ PD\ KDYH RQ WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW DVVHVVPHQWµ 3RZHUFR DW > @ 6HH 6HFWLRQV DQG

EHORZ IRU IXUWKHU GLVFXVVLRQ RI WKLV WHFKQLTXH

&DWHJRU\ $ 6HH 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 3RZHUFR DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW

> @ > @ > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @ ,QWHUHVWLQJO\ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQ 3RZHUFR VLPSO\ DFFHSWHG WKH DPRXQW FODLPHG E\ WKH DSSOLFDQW EHFDXVH LW ZDV ´QRW ODUJHµ DQG ZDV

´FRQVLGHUHG UHDVRQDEOHµ 3RZHUFR DW > @

&DWHJRU\ % 6HH (OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW > @ > @

&DWHJRU\ $ 6HH 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 4DQWDV +& DW

> @ > @

4DQWDV DW > @ 7KHVH VLPSOLI\LQJ DVVXPSWLRQV DUH RIWHQ XQUHDOLVWLF

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 5XDSHKX DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ DQG 1=5)8 DW

> @ > @ QRWH WKDW VXFK EHQHILWV PXVW EH FDXWLRXVO\ HYDOXDWHG

4DQWDV DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ 1HYHUWKHOHVV LW ZDV DGRSWHG IRU WKH SXUSRVHV RI FDOFXODWLQJ WKH SXEOLF EHQHILWV DULVLQJ RXW RI WKH SURSRVHG DUUDQJHPHQWV

1RWH WKDW WKH GLVFRXQWLQJ RI WKH DSSOLFDQW·V FODLP LV D VHSDUDWH PDWWHU IURP WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V GLVFRXQWLQJ RI WKHLU RZQ FDOFXODWLRQV

Once quantified, quantified intangibles and quantified tangibles are weighed and balanced in the same manner. This makes sense; logically a dollar's worth of quantified intangibles should have the same weighting as a dollar's worth of quantified tangibles. If that were not the case the quantification exercise would be futile.

2.2 Unquantified intangibles

If intangible benefits are not quantified, the Commission is required to weigh quantified (and possibly some unquantified) detriments against quantified and unquantified benefits. It must compare dollars and non-dollars. As such, it must undertake a qualitative assessment of the benefits and detriments. This section analyses whether, and the extent to which, unquantified intangibles have been given weight.

2.2.Ł CATEGORY Ł: VAGUE CLAIMS WITH FAR REACHING CONSEQUENCES

As discussed in Section 1.5.1, these are the least tangible of all the benefits. This means that any bias the Commission might have against intangible benefits is more likely to be evident in its discussion of this category of benefits.

Category ŁA: “Feel-good” factors

In its decisions, the Commission has shown a reluctance to place any weight upon “feel-good” factors. In NZRFU 2, the Commission indicated that it was disinclined to place any weight upon a claimed benefit of increased “feel-good” for New Zealanders as a result of better international performances by New Zealand squads, because of the tenuous nature of the benefit and the weak and indirect link between the proposal and the benefit. In NZ Dairy 2, Kiwi, Kiwifruit and Midland Health, evidential problems meant that the Commission placed little or no weight

7KH TXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV ZKHWKHU LQWDQJLEOH RU WDQJLEOH DUH XVXDOO\ VHW RXW LQ D WDEOH DQG DGGHG WRJHWKHU WR JLYH WKH WRWDO VXP RI WKH TXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV 6HH 3RZHUFR DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @

(OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ 1=5)8 DW

> @

$ TXDOLWDWLYH DVVHVVPHQW UHOLHV RQ ´H[SHULHQFH DQG MXGJPHQWµ $QVHWW DW > @ DQG FDQ EH FRQWUDVWHG ZLWK D TXDQWLWDWLYH DSSURDFK ZKLFK PHDVXUHV EHQHILWV DQG GHWULPHQWV LQ D FRPPRQ XQLW (YHQ LQ D TXDOLWDWLYH DVVHVVPHQW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ QHHGV WR GHPRQVWUDWH WKH ZHLJKW DSSOLFDEOH WR EHQHILWV LI WKH ZHLJKLQJ DQG EDODQFLQJ SURFHVV LV WR EH PHDQLQJIXO )OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @

1=5)8 DW > @

upon the avoidance of community and industry disharmony and the promotion of community well-being.

The preservation of Air New Zealand as New Zealand's national flag carrier has been claimed as a benefit on two occasions. In Ansett the Commission seemed to place no weight upon it, but in Qantas the Commission and High Court indicated that a value should be attached to it. However, no explicit indication was given in Qantas of the weighting that should be ascribed to it. The Commission appeared to only have regard to the quantified benefits in its final analysis. Whilst the High Court indicated that the benefit was being considered, the magnitude of the quantified detriments makes it difficult to gauge what weight was placed upon it. The fact that the benefit was grouped with other benefits of a speculative nature under a general heading at the end of the benefit section, may suggest that the High Court did not consider that it was of particular importance.

Category ŁB: Assisting New Zealand's general interests at an international level

Category 1B benefits have never been accorded any real weight. In Ansett, whilst the Commission acknowledged that an improvement in diplomatic relations between New Zealand and Australia was a benefit of some significance, there was insufficient evidence of its extent to determine what weight should be accorded to it. Thus the Commission seemed to assign little or no weight to it. Benefits

1= 'DLU\ DW > @ > @ 1= 'DLU\ +& DW LZL DW > @ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ 0LGODQG

+HDOWK DW > @ ,Q 1= 'DLU\ DQG .LZL WKH &RPPLVVLRQ GRXEWHG ZKHWKHU WKHUH ZDV D QH[XV EHWZHHQ WKH DYRLGDQFH RI FRPPXQLW\ GLVKDUPRQ\ DQG WKH SURSRVHG PHUJHUV 1= 'DLU\ DW > @

.LZL DW > @ ,Q .LZLIUXLW WKHUH ZDV QRWKLQJ WR VXJJHVW WKDW WKH DJUHHPHQW VHHNLQJ WR EH DXWKRULVHG ZRXOG HOLPLQDWH SUREOHPV ZLWK LQGXVWU\ GLVKDUPRQ\ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ ,Q 0LGODQG

+HDOWK LW ZDV WKRXJKW WKDW WKH EHQHILW WR WKH FRPPXQLW\·V ZHOO EHLQJ ZRXOG DFFUXH ZKHWKHU RU QRW WKH DFWLYLW\ ZDV DXWKRULVHG 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @

$QVHWW DW > @ > @ > @ $W > @ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQGLFDWHG WKDW LW ZDV EHVW FRQVLGHUHG XQGHU WKH RWKHU EHQHILW KHDGLQJV

4DQWDV DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ VWDWHG WKDW LW KDG D ´QRQ TXDQWLILDEOH V\PEROLF YDOXHµ 6HH 6HFWLRQ IRU DQ HYDOXDWLRQ RI KRZ WKH WUHDWPHQW RI WKLV EHQHILW KDV FKDQJHG RYHU WLPH

4DQWDV DW > @ 7KH EHQHILW ZDV DVVLJQHG D YDOXH RI LQ WKH WDEOH DQG WKH EHQHILWV ZHUH VDLG WR DPRXQW WR P ZLWK QR UHIHUHQFH EHLQJ PDGH WR XQTXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ ZDV FULWLFLVHG E\ WKH +LJK &RXUW IRU WKLV 4DQWDV +& DW > @

4DQWDV +& DW > @ > @

7KH YDOXH RI WKH TXDQWLILHG GHWULPHQWV ZDV PRUH WKDQ GRXEOH WKH YDOXH RI WKH TXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV 7KLV PHDQW WKDW WKH XQTXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV ZHUH QHYHU JRLQJ WR EH VXIILFLHQW WR WLS WKH EDODQFH

4DQWDV +& DW > @ 7KH KHDGLQJ ZDV ´RWKHU EHQHILWVµ

$QVHWW DW > @ 7KLV HYLGHQWLDO SUREOHP DURVH IURP WKH LQWDQJLELOLW\ RI WKH EHQHILW 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ VWDWHG WKDW LW ZDV GLIILFXOW WR VHH H[DFWO\ ZKDW WKH YDOXH RI WKH EHQHILW ZDV DQG KRZ LW FRXOG EH HYDOXDWHG

under the Australia New Zealand Closer Economic Relations (CER) Trade Agreement have also been given little or no weight, on the basis that they have already been assessed under some of the other heads, such as efficiency improvements.

In Qantas, the Commission identified reduced risk to national security as a public benefit. However, there was no further discussion regarding its significance and extent. The Commission has made it clear that for a benefit to be given weight, the applicant must provide evidence of its existence and extent. The lack of discussion in Qantas regarding the extent of any national security benefit, suggests that it was accorded very minimal or no weight. Nevertheless, the fact that the Commission raised the benefit, suggests that the Commission may consider that national security benefits could be of real significance in some instances. On appeal, the High Court made no reference to the national security benefit, suggesting that it did not consider it to be of any importance.

Conclusion on the weight attached to Category Ł benefits

Whilst the Commission and courts appear willing to accord some weight to the benefits within this category, in no case have they been given more than a minimal weighting. However, it is not the lack of tangibility but the lack of causal nexus or the minimal extent of the claimed benefit that is cited as the reason for this low weighting. The onus is on the applicant to provide evidence of the causal nexus between the practice and the benefit, and the extent of the benefit. If insufficient evidence is provided to discharge this onus, no weight can be given to the benefit. This means that it is not possible to positively conclude that the lack of weight accorded to this category of benefits is solely because of their intangibility.

Interestingly, it is probably the very features that make these benefits so intangible that makes it so difficult to provide evidence of the causal nexus and the extent of the benefit. Category 1 benefits often arise quite indirectly, flowing through a

7ZR RI WKH IRXU &RPPLVVLRQHUV &RPPLVVLRQHUV %ROODUG DQG 6WDSOHWRQ ODWHU VXJJHVWHG WKDW WKH QH[XV EHWZHHQ WKH EHQHILW DQG WKH DFTXLVLWLRQ KDG QRW EHHQ DGHTXDWHO\ VKRZQ $QVHWW DW > @ 7KLV LV D IXUWKHU UHDVRQ WR JLYH PLQLPDO RU QR ZHLJKWLQJ WR WKH EHQHILW

$PFRU DW > @ 1= 'DLU\ DW > @ > @

4DQWDV DW > @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU DW > @

6HH $QVHWW DW > @ LQ SDUWLFXODU

1=5)8 DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @ .LZLIUXLW DW > @

1= 'DLU\ DW > @ 1= 'DLU\ +& DW LZL DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH :KDNDWX DW > @

number of channels, meaning that their existence and nature is controversial. This makes the demonstration of a casual nexus problematic. Because they arise outside of markets and affect a large group of people but only marginally, there is no obvious economic framework in which to assess their value. This makes it difficult to provide evidence of their extent.

There is an alternative explanation for the low weighting attached to Category 1 benefits. Unlike the benefits in the other categories, Category 1 benefits are not efficiency gains. The Commission has stated on a number of occasions that greater weight is to be given to efficiency claims than other claims. This is presumably a reflection of section 3A of the Act, which compels the Commission to have regard to any efficiencies that may result from the conduct which is sought to be authorised. The Commission appears to have read this as requiring greater weight to be placed upon efficiency than non-efficiency benefits. Such an interpretation would justify a lower weighting for Category 1 benefits.

As discussed in Section 1.5.2, these benefits usually accrue to the broader community. The 1991 and 1992 Reviews of the Commerce Act remark that wider social benefit claims are generally accorded a low weighting, and are never a significant element in the decisions. Dr Michael Pickford's writings support this view. Writing in 1989, he opined that the decisions tend to emphasise the

(IILFLHQF\ EHLQJ XVHG LQ WKH WUDGLWLRQDO FRPSHWLWLRQ ODZ VHQVH DQG VR LQFRUSRUDWLQJ DOORFDWLYH SURGXFWLYH DQG G\QDPLF HIILFLHQF\

%ULHUOH\ DW > @ $QVHWW DW > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ 3RZHUFR DW > @ ,Q RWKHU GHFLVLRQV LW KDV VWUHVVHG WKDW WKH HPSKDVLV RU IRFXV LV RQ HFRQRPLF HIILFLHQF\ 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ > @

1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @

1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ 6HH DOVR &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW :KLOVW WKH

5HYLHZ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW UHFRJQLVHV WKLV EDVLF SRVLWLRQ LW QRWHV WKDW ZKHUH WKH MXGJPHQW RQ WKH EDVLV RI HIILFLHQF\ LV D ILQH RQH LW LV SRVVLEOH WKDW RWKHU IDFWRUV PD\ WLOW WKH EDODQFH 0LQVLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH 7KH 7UHDVXU\ 'HSDUWPHQW RI -XVWLFH DQG 'HSDUWPHQW RI WKH 3ULPH 0LQLVWHU DQG &DELQHW 5HYLHZ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW 'LVFXVVLRQ 'RFXPHQW 0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH :HOOLQJWRQ

DW

0RUH SUHFLVHO\ V $ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW VWLSXODWHV WKDW ´>Z@KHUH WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LV UHTXLUHG XQGHU WKLV $FW WR GHWHUPLQH ZKHWKHU RU QRW RU WKH H[WHQW WR ZKLFK FRQGXFW ZLOO UHVXOW RU ZLOO EH OLNHO\ WR UHVXOW LQ D EHQHILW WR WKH SXEOLF WKH &RPPLVVLRQ VKDOO KDYH UHJDUG WR DQ\ HIILFLHQFLHV WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ FRQVLGHUV ZLOO UHVXOW RU ZLOO EH OLNHO\ WR UHVXOW IURP WKDW FRQGXFWµ

6HH 6HFWLRQ EHORZ IRU DQ H[DPLQDWLRQ RI ZKHWKHU WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V LQWHUSUHWDWLRQ RI WKH HIIHFW RI V $ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW LV FRUUHFW

0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH HW DO DW 0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH 7KH 7UHDVXU\ DQG 'HSDUWPHQW RI

-XVWLFH DQG 'HSDUWPHQW RI WKH 3ULPH 0LQLVWHU DQG &DELQHW 5HYLHZ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW

0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH :HOOLQJWRQ DW +RZHYHU WKH 5HYLHZ QRWHG WKDW LW LV SRVVLEOH WKDW WKH\ FRXOG RFFDVLRQDOO\ EH VLJQLILFDQW

0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH HW DO DW

economic, rather than the broader social effects. Later in 1993, he noted that benefits of a social nature had not been decisive in any case. To the extent that Category 1 benefits are wider social benefits, these comments are also applicable to those benefits.

Category 2A: Environmental benefits

A reduction in adverse environmental effects has been claimed on three occasions. In Ravensdown the Commission held that there were possibly some environmental public benefits, but felt that there was insufficient information available to allow a firm conclusion to be drawn. In the final analysis, it stated that the value of the public benefits was equivalent to the quantified benefits, plus some items which were difficult to identify or quantify. Commissioner Taylor indicated that quantified detriments and benefits were fairly similar, with quantified detriments being slightly higher in magnitude. Yet, even after taking into account the environmental benefits, he was not satisfied that the detriments were outweighed by the public benefits. The fact that there were also significant unquantified detriments complicates the analysis, and so the actual significance attached to the environmental benefits cannot be accurately gauged. However, the Commission's indication that it had insufficient information to evaluate their extent, tends to suggest that little weight was attached to them.

0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG ´&RPSHWLWLRQ 3ROLF\ 0HUJHUV DQG WKH 1HW 6RFLDO %HQHILW 7HVWµ LQ %ROODUG $ODQ

HG 7KH (FRQRPLFV RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW 5HVHDUFK 0RQRJUDSK 1HZ =HDODQG ,QVWLWXWH RI (FRQRPLF 5HVHDUFK :HOOLQJWRQ DW

3LFNIRUG DW ,QVWHDG DXWKRULVDWLRQ GHFLVLRQV DUH EDVHG PDLQO\ RQ WKH JDLQV DQG ORVVHV RI HIILFLHQF\ $UJXDEO\ &DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV DUH HIILFLHQF\ EHQHILWV WR WKH H[WHQW WKDW WKH\ UHVXOW LQ D EHWWHU DOORFDWLRQ RI UHVRXUFHV

5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ > @

,ELG DW > @ 7KXV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ DW OHDVW FUHDWHG WKH DSSHDUDQFH WKDW WKH\ KDG FRQVLGHUHG WKH XQTXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV

7KH &RPPLVVLRQ TXDQWLILHG GHWULPHQWV DV O\LQJ EHWZHHQ P DQG P SHU DQQXP DQG EHQHILWV DV O\LQJ EHWZHHQ P DQG P SHU DQQXP ,ELG DW > @ &RPPLVVLRQHU 7D\ORU FRQVLGHUHG WKH WUXH YDOXH RI WKH GHWULPHQWV WR EH LQ WKH PLGGOH RI WKH UDQJH ,ELG DW > @ &RPPLVVLRQHUV 6WDSOHWRQ DQG %URZQ LQGLFDWHG WKDW WKH\ WKRXJKW WKDW WKH GHWULPHQWV OD\ DW WKH XSSHU HQG RI WKH UDQJH ,ELG DW > @

,ELG DW > @

,ELG 1DPHO\ D ORVV RI SURGXFW TXDOLW\ ,ELG DW > @ $ ORVV RI LQYHVWPHQW HIILFLHQF\ ZDV DOVR VDLG WR EH SRVVLEOH ,ELG DW > @

In Omv the Commission did not consider that a case had been made for significant weight to be attached to environmental benefits. This essentially seemed to be a problem of proving that the benefit would actually eventuate.

It was the Commission, rather than the applicant that raised the possibility of environmental benefits in Qantas. The Commission considered that these effects were likely to be relatively minor. However, the fact that the Commission raised them may suggest that it considers that they could be of real significance in some instances.

Category 2B: Health benefits

In Midland Health, the Commission accepted that there might be some benefits in the short term to the mental health of patients from the anti-competitive arrangement that the applicants sought to be authorised. However, in its final analysis the Commission indicated that it did not consider that the nexus between the benefits and the arrangement had been sufficiently demonstrated. This suggests that very little or no weight was accorded to the benefit to patients' mental health.

Improved safety has been claimed as a benefit in four decisions. Whilst the Commission accepted that there was a public benefit arising from improved safety in both Fletcher and Qantas, it did not discuss the weight to be accorded to it. This may suggest that the Commission did not consider the benefit to be significant in either of these cases. However, the fact that it was the Commission that raised

2PY DW > @

,ELG 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ GLG QRW DFFHSW WKDW WKHUH ZRXOG EH EHWWHU HQYLURQPHQWDO RXWFRPHV LQ WKH IDFWXDO FRPSDUHG WR WKH FRXQWHUIDFWXDO

7KHVH EHQHILWV LQFOXGHG D UHGXFWLRQ LQ SROOXWLRQ YLVXDO GLVDPHQLW\ DQG QRLVH

4DQWDV DW > @

0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ 7KHVH DURVH IURP SDWLHQWV KDYLQJ UHDG\ DFFHVV WR WKHLU IDPLOLHV WR FRPPXQLW\ VXSSRUW DQG WR YRFDWLRQDO DQG UHFUHDWLRQDO VHUYLFHV ,W ZDV DOVR LQ OLQH ZLWK WKH JRYHUQPHQW·V SROLF\ RQ DFFHVV WR PHQWDO KHDOWK IDFLOLWLHV 0LGODQG DW > @

,ELG DW > @ ,Q WKH DEVHQFH RI WKH DJUHHPHQW WKH SURSRVHG PHQWDO KHDOWK IDFLOLW\ ZDV OLNHO\ WR EH EXLOW LQ WKH VDPH SODFH :DLNDWR +RVSLWDO DQG VR VLPLODU EHQHILWV ZRXOG HQVXH XQGHU WKH IDFWXDO DQG FRXQWHUIDFWXDO

,Q 4DQWDV LW ZDV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ UDWKHU WKDQ WKH DSSOLFDQW WKDW LGHQWLILHG WKH VDIHW\ EHQHILW

4DQWDV DW > @

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ ,Q )OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH WKH EHQHILW ZDV FODLPHG LQ FRQMXQFWLRQ ZLWK D UHGXFWLRQ LQ URDG PDLQWHQDQFH FRVWV $OWKRXJK WKH EHQHILW SHUWDLQLQJ WR UHGXFHG URDG XVDJH ZDV TXDQWLILHG LQ WKDW GHFLVLRQ LW PD\ KDYH RQO\ UHODWHG WR WKH SDUW RI WKH EHQHILW DWWULEXWDEOH WR UHGXFHG URDG PDLQWHQDQFH FRVWV

the possibility of public safety benefits in Qantas may indicate that it considers that they could be of real significance in some cases.

A claim of improved safety was not accepted in Natural Gas Waikato on the grounds that no problems with existing safety procedures had been suggested, and hence no benefit would arise under the factual. Nor was it accepted in Speedway, on the basis that the benefit would arise with or without the presence of the anti- competitive agreement.

Category 2C: Social benefits

These benefits have not been given any real weight in the decisions. Whilst the Commission in Consortium remarked that it fully appreciated that closures of freezing works would cause substantial distress, it was not convinced that the social benefits accruing to some as a result of the agreement to close one freezing works, would outweigh the social costs to others from the agreement. Accordingly, the Commission saw no social benefits accruing from the proposal. Nor did the Commission in Tasman accept that a reduction in the volume logged would have adverse consequences for the township of Murupara. The increased stability of rural communities was said to have no more than a minor beneficial impact in Grape Growers.

Although the stabilisation of employment was accepted as a public benefit in Fletcher, the Commission did not discuss the weight to be accorded to it, suggesting minimal or no weight was given to it. The enhancement of job security was considered in Whakatu and Amcor. It was not accepted on the facts in Whakatu, and although it was accepted in Amcor, there was no discussion regarding the weight to be attached to it.

1DWXUDO *DV :DLNDWR DW > @

6SHHGZD\ DW > @

&RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @

,ELG DW > @

7DVPDQ DW > @

*UDSH *URZHUV DW > @ > @

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @

:KDNDWX DW > @ > @ $PFRU DW > @

:KDNDWX DW > @ ,Q IDFW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ FRQVLGHUHG WKDW RQ EDODQFH WKHUH ZDV D QHW GHWULPHQW WR HPSOR\HHV IURP WKH DJUHHPHQW WR FORVH D PHDW ZRUNV

$PFRU DW > @

Conclusion on the weight attached to Category 2 benefits

Very little weight has been attached to benefits falling within this category. As for Category 1, this low weighting may be explained by the difficulty facing the applicant of proving a causal nexus between the benefit and the practice, and proving the extent of the benefit. Just as with the Category 1 benefits, arguably it is the very features that make these benefits intangible, that make it so difficult to provide affirmative evidence of the causal link and the extent of the benefit.

Category 3A: Increased quality and choice for consumers

This benefit has been claimed in a large number of cases and it has been given significant weighting in at least one case. In a number of other cases this benefit has been accepted but the weight to be prescribed to it has not been discussed, perhaps suggesting that minimal weight was attached to it. Nevertheless, the Commission seems more inclined to give benefits in this category weight than those in the first two categories.

In Qantas, the High Court accepted that the appellants had demonstrated that substantial online benefits would accrue from the proposed alliance and stated that although they could not be safely expressed in monetary terms, they should be given considerable weight in the final analysis. The fact that the High Court dealt with these benefits in a separate section to the other unquantified benefits, confirmed how important it considered them to be.

In Transpower, the Commission indicated that it considered improved security of supply to be a real benefit, despite the fact that it was described rather than quantified. It referred to the extremely large cost of a total system collapse and

4DQWDV +& DW > @

$PFRU DW > @ 1DWXUDO *DV :DLNDWR DW > @ 7HOHFRP &$ DW $QVHWW DW > @ 3RZHUFR DW

> @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @

4DQWDV +& DW > @ 7KH +LJK &RXUW FULWLFLVHG WKH &RPPLVVLRQ IRU VXEVFULELQJ D YDOXH RI ]HUR WR WKHP LQ WKHLU ILQDO DQDO\VLV 4DQWDV +& DW > @

2QOLQH EHQHILWV KDG WKHLU RZQ VHFWLRQ ZKHUHDV DOO RWKHU XQTXDQWLILHG EHQHILWV ZHUH GHDOW ZLWK XQGHU RQH EURDG KHDGLQJ

7UDQVSRZHU DW > @

stated that any reduction in the likelihood of this occurring was a public benefit. However, in that case the absence of detriments meant that any magnitude of benefit would be sufficient to make out a case for authorisation.

There are four decisions dealing with stock exchange regulations in which benefits including better quality clearing services, ensuring integrity in the market and increasing confidence in the market have been accepted. In each of these decisions, these benefits were found to outweigh the detriments arising from the lessening of competition. However, the detriments in each of these cases were not large, and so it is difficult to gauge whether the benefits were really accorded significant weight.

Once again, in some cases this sub-category of benefits has been given little or no weighting because of the difficulties of proving a causal nexus between the proposed activity and the benefit. However, this seems to be much less of a problem than with the previous two categories of benefits. This probably stems from the fact that this benefit usually accrues to individuals in the immediate market, and so the benefit does not tend to flow through as many channels, making the proof of a causal nexus much easier.

In TeamTalk and Ruapehu benefits within this sub-category were given little weight because the Commission felt that they had already been accounted for in the consideration of other benefits. In Ruapehu, greater enjoyment as a consequence of an improved skiing experience was held to manifest itself in increased skier days. The valuation of skier days incorporated both the benefit

,ELG DW > @

,ELG DW > @

1=6( DW > @ > @ 1=6( DW > @ > @ 6)( DW > @ > @ 6)( DW > @ > @

1=6( DQG 6)( H[SOLFLWO\ QRWH WKLV SRLQW 1=6( DW > @ 6)( DW > @ > @ 7KH YHU\ SXUSRVH RI WKH DJUHHPHQWV ZHUH WR DFKLHYH WKHVH EHQHILWV IRU SDUWLFLSDQWV LQ WKH VWRFN H[FKDQJH

.LZLIUXLW DW > @ > @ 6SHHGZD\ DW > @ ,Q WKRVH GHFLVLRQV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQGLFDWHG WKDW WKH UHVSHFWLYH EHQHILWV GLG QRW GHSHQG XSRQ WKH H[LVWHQFH RI DQ DJUHHPHQW 6HH DOVR $QVHWW ,Q UHODWLRQ WR LPSURYHG LQWHUQDWLRQDO SDVVHQJHU DLU VHUYLFHV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQGLFDWHG LI $LU 1HZ

=HDODQG ZHUH WR EHFRPH OHVV FRPSHWLWLYH RWKHU DLUOLQHV ZRXOG ILOO WKH JDS $QVHWW DW > @ ,Q UHODWLRQ WR LPSURYHG LQWHUQDWLRQDO IUHLJKW VHUYLFHV IRU H[SRUWHUV DQG LPSRUWHUV &RPPLVVLRQHUV

%ROODUG DQG 6WDSOHWRQ KHOG WKDW $LU 1HZ =HDODQG KDG QRW DGHTXDWHO\ VKRZQ WKH QH[XV EHWZHHQ WKH DFTXLVLWLRQ DQG WKH FODLPHG EHQHILW $QVHWW DW > @ 6HH DOVR 9HJHWDEOH *URZHUV DW > @ ,Q WKDW FDVH WKH &RPPLVVLRQ FRXOG ILQG QR OLQN EHWZHHQ WKH EHQHILW DQG WKH DUUDQJHPHQW

$QG VR FDQ EH FODVVLILHG DV D PDUNHW DQG GLUHFW EHQHILW 6HH 6HFWLRQV DQG

7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @

5XDSHKX DW > @

7KH EOXH DQG UHG DUHDV UHSUHVHQW WKH FRQVXPHU VXUSOXV WKDW DFFUXHV WR FXVWRPHUV IURP SXUFKDVLQJ WKH VHUYLFH 1RWH WKDW SDUW RI WKLV FRQVXPHU VXUSOXV ZRXOG EH DFKLHYHG E\ WKH SXUFKDVH RI DQ DOWHUQDWLYH DOEHLW OHVV SUHIHUUHG VHUYLFH EOXH DUHD DQG VR WKH LQFUHDVH LQ FRQVXPHU VXUSOXV IURP LQFUHDVHG FXVWRPHU FKRLFH UHSUHVHQWV D VPDOOHU DUHD UHG DUHD
Quantity
Q*
D
P*
S
EHQHILW IURP LQFUHDVHG

FRQVXPHU FKRLFH
FIGURE 3: Increased choice for consumers

Price

accruing to producers in terms of increased profits, and that accruing to consumers in the form of greater enjoyment. In TeamTalk, the Commission seemed to suggest that increased choice for consumers was reflected in the additional profit TeamTalk would receive. Whilst this is true to some extent, the Commission may have erred in part. Only some of the increased satisfaction accruing to consumers from greater choice will be reflected in the price they pay for the services they purchase. The market price for a good or service is often less than the maximum amount which some consumers

would be willing to pay. This difference represents what is known in conventional economic terms as a “consumer surplus”. Consumer surplus is the utility that accrues to consumers beyond what they have paid for. The diagram above illustrates the area of consumer surplus. Contrary to the view taken in TeamTalk, this represents a benefit to the public that should be considered when the public benefit test is applied.

By contrast, it is useful to consider the loss of product quality or consumer choice on the detriment side. The same difficulties of quantification logically must arise. The very nature of anti-competitive practices and acquisitions mean that in virtually all decisions the loss of consumer choice will be a relevant detriment. A reduction in consumer choice reflects a loss of allocative efficiency. A loss of allocative

7KLV LV NQRZQ DV WKH SURGXFHU VXUSOXV DQG UHSUHVHQWV WKH YDOXH WKDW SURGXFHUV UHFHLYH RYHU DQG DERYH ZKDW WKH\ ZRXOG EH SUHSDUHG WR VHOO LW IRU VHH )UDQN DQG %HUQDQNH DW

7KLV LV NQRZQ DV WKH FRQVXPHU VXUSOXV DQG UHSUHVHQWV WKH YDOXH WKDW WKH JRRG KDV WR FRQVXPHUV RYHU DQG DERYH ZKDW WKH\ SD\ IRU LW VHH ,ELG DW

7HDP7DON DW > @

,Q WKH HQG WKLV HUURU SUREDEO\ GLG QRW PDNH DQ\ GLIIHUHQFH EHFDXVH WKH &RPPLVVLRQ VHHPHG WR EH RI WKH YLHZ WKDW WKH PDJQLWXGH RI WKH EHQHILW ZDV VPDOO ,ELG DW > @

efficiency has two effects: a loss of consumer choice and an increase in price. This makes it difficult to determine the extent of detriment attributable to the loss of consumer choice. Hence it is more informative to look at losses of product quality. This detriment is often raised in decisions. A loss of quality was held to be a detriment of significant magnitude in Hoyts, Ansett and Ravensdown. By parity of reasoning, an increase in product or service quality should be able to be accorded significant weighting if the facts warrant it.

Category 3B: Improved information in the marketplace

This benefit arose in Life Underwriters and Electricity Corporation. It was also raised in Grape Growers but rejected on the facts. The focus of the applicant's submissions in Life Underwriters centred around an improvement in the ability of consumers to make informed decisions based on accurate information. Whilst a revised code was authorised subject to conditions, the detriments in that case were not particularly significant. In Electricity Corporation the Commission made it clear that it had given some weight to having better informed market participants, but did not indicate how significant the benefit was, except to say that the sum of all the benefits were significant, even though they had not been quantified.

Category 3C: Improvements in bargaining relationships

Greater equality of negotiating power has been raised as a benefit in four cases. The basic philosophy seems to be that if there is already a reasonable parity of bargaining power, there will be no public benefit from increasing the weaker party's

$ ORVV RI DOORFDWLYH HIILFLHQF\ RFFXUV ZKHQ D ILUP UDLVHV WKH SULFH DERYH WKH FRPSHWLWLYH OHYHO DQG VR UHVWULFWV WKH TXDQWLW\ VROG LQ WKH PDUNHW &RPPHUFH &OHDULQJ +RXVH DW

1= 'DLU\ DW > @ +R\WV DW > @ > @ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 3RZHUFR DW > @ > @ 7HDP7DON 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW

> @ > @ > @ > @ ,QWHUHVWLQJO\ ORVV RI TXDOLW\ KDV RQO\ EHHQ UDLVHG LQ WKH SDVW ILIWHHQ \HDUV

+R\WV DW > @ > @ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @

*UDSH *URZHUV DW > @ 7KH VKDULQJ RI NQRZOHGJH EHWZHHQ JURZHUV WR HQDEOH SULFH QHJRWLDWLRQV WR WDNH SODFH LQ D PRUH LQIRUPHG HQYLURQPHQW ZDV UHMHFWHG EHFDXVH WKH SUHVHQW H[WHQW RI GLVDGYDQWDJH ZDV QRW VXEVWDQWLDO DQG WKH FROOHFWLYLW\ VKDULQJ RI NQRZOHGJH ZRXOG QRW SURYLGH PRUH WKDQ D PDUJLQDO DPRXQW RI SXEOLF EHQHILW

/LIH 8QGHUZULWHUV DW > @

,ELG DW > @ > @

(OHFWULFLW\ &RUSRUDWLRQ DW > @

,ELG DW > @ > @

negotiating position. It was for this reason that the benefit was rejected in

Kiwifruit and Grape Growers.

Two types of benefits were claimed under this head in Enerco. The applicant, Enerco, suggested that stronger negotiating power would enable it to negotiate a lower price for gas. The Commission held that this was only a benefit to the extent that lower wholesale prices would be passed on to customers. Enerco also suggested that it would be able to use its strengthened negotiating power to secure access to other retail gas markets and to compete in them and act as an industry watchdog. The Commission felt that at most, only a small public benefit could be attributed to this.

In NZRFU 2, the Commission accepted that greater leverage for the NZRFU in its negotiations over international television rights, sponsorship and revenue sharing arrangements was a public benefit, but only to the extent that those revenue flows were derived from foreign sources. Because the nexus between improved international performances and the introduction of the arrangements was weak, the resulting benefits were classified as relatively minor.

In Brierley, the applicant claimed bargaining difficulties would arise under the counterfactual. Whilst the Commission acknowledged the possibility could not be precluded, they felt that the likelihood was very low and so consequently gave little weight to it.

.LZLIUXLW DW > @ *UDSH *URZHUV DW > @

.LZLIUXLW DW > @

*UDSH *URZHUV DW > @

(QHUFR DW > @ :KHWKHU WKLV UHSUHVHQWV WKH FXUUHQW ODZ LV XQFOHDU 3ULRU WR WKH DPHQGPHQW RI WKH $FW LQ WKH +LJK &RXUW KHOG WKDW SXEOLF EHQHILWV HYHQ LI QRW VKRZQ WR KDYH EHHQ SDVVHG GLUHFWO\ RQ WR FRQVXPHUV KDG DQ HOHPHQW RI SXEOLF EHQHILW )LVKHU 3D\NHO +& DW 1= 'DLU\

+& DW +RZHYHU V $ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW DGGHG E\ V RI WKH &RPPHUFH

$PHQGPHQW $FW DUJXDEO\ LQWURGXFHV D GLVWULEXWLRQDO ELDV LQ IDYRXU RI FRQVXPHUV DQG VR PD\ FKDQJH WKH SRVLWLRQ )RU IXUWKHU GLVFXVVLRQ VHH &RPPHUFH &OHDULQJ +RXVH DW

5H[ $KGDU ´&RQVXPHUV 5HGLVWULEXWLRQ RI ,QFRPH DQG WKH 3XUSRVH RI &RPSHWLWLRQ /DZµ

> @ (XURSHDQ &RPSHWLWLRQ /DZ 5HYLHZ *HRII %HUWUDP ´:KDW·V :URQJ ZLWK 1HZ =HDODQG·V 3XEOLF %HQHILW 7HVW"µ 1HZ =HDODQG (FRQRPLF 3DSHUV

(QHUFR DW > @

1=5)8 DW > @ 2WKHUZLVH LW ZRXOG VLPSO\ DPRXQW WR D UHGLVWULEXWLRQ RI LQFRPH EHWZHHQ GLIIHUHQW JURXSV

,ELG

%ULHUOH\ DW > @

,ELG

Conclusion on the weight attached to Category 3 benefits

The Commission and courts have shown a greater willingness to place weight on benefits within this category, than the previous two categories. Difficulties of proving a causal nexus are much less prevalent. It seems that Category 3 benefits are of a different order than Category 1 and 2 benefits.

Tourism benefits have been raised, but not quantified in three decisions. In each of these decisions, little weight was accorded to them, because of difficulty proving a causal nexus between the proposed activity and increased tourism.

Category 4B: Enhanced export opportunities

These benefits have had a real influence in a number of decisions. In Amcor the main benefit arising from the proposal was to allow access to the Australian market. The development and maintenance of a unified marketing effort, so as to facilitate the flow of fruit overseas was given significant weight in Kiwifruit, and appeared to be the key factor for the Commission in authorising the agreement.

As for the other categories, in some decisions little or no weight has been given to these benefits because of difficulties proving a causal nexus between the proposed activity and the enhanced export opportunity.

6HH 4DQWDV +& DW > @ LQ SDUWLFXODU ZKHUH WKH +LJK &RXUW JDYH FRQVLGHUDEOH ZHLJKW WR RQOLQH EHQHILWV )RU H[DPSOHV RI GHFLVLRQV ZKHUH WKH &RPPLVVLRQ JDYH VLJQLILFDQW ZHLJKW WR GHWULPHQWV

WKDW ZRXOG IDOO ZLWKLQ WKLV FDWHJRU\ VHH +R\WV DW > @ > @ $QVHWW DW > @ > @ > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ 7KHUH DUH DOVR D QXPEHU RI GHFLVLRQV ZKHUH &DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV GHWHUPLQHG WKH RXWFRPH RI WKH FDVH EXW EHFDXVH RI WKH ODFN RI GHWULPHQW LW FDQQRW EH DVFHUWDLQHG ZKHWKHU WKH\ ZHUH DFWXDOO\ RI VLJQLILFDQW ZHLJKW 7UDQVSRZHU 6)( DW 6)( 1=6( 1=6( /LIH 8QGHUZULWHUV

$QVHWW 1=5)8 1=5)8

$QVHWW DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @

$PFRU DW > @ 7KH HQKDQFHPHQW LQ H[SRUW SRWHQWLDO ZDV JLYHQ ZHLJKW QRW VR PXFK EHFDXVH RI WKH LQFUHDVH LQ H[SRUW RSSRUWXQLWLHV LWVHOI EXW EHFDXVH RI WKH OLNHOLKRRG WKDW LW ZRXOG LPSDFW IDYRXUDEO\ RQ WKH 1HZ =HDODQG HFRQRP\ YLD LPSURYHG HPSOR\PHQW UHJLRQDO GHYHORSPHQW DQG

IXUWKHU SURVSHULW\ $PFRU DW > @ > @

.LZLIUXLW DW > @ > @ > @ 0RVW RI WKH RWKHU FODLPHG EHQHILWV ZHUH QRW DFFHSWHG

.LZLIUXLW DW > @

*RRGPDQ )LHOGHU > @ 1=5)8 > @ 1=5)8 > @ $QRWKHU UHDVRQ IRU JLYLQJ WKH EHQHILW OLWWOH ZHLJKW LQ *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU ZDV WKDW WKHUH ZDV QR UHDOLVWLF SURVSHFW WKDW WKH EHQHILW ZRXOG EH SDVVHG RQ WR WKH 1HZ =HDODQG FRQVXPHU *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU DW > @ 7KH +LJK &RXUW ODWHU KHOG WKDW

Category 4C: Improvements in international competitiveness

This benefit may tend to be claimed when it is difficult to prove that there is an enhancement in export opportunities, making it more speculative in nature. If this is the case, it is likely that this sub-category of benefits will be given less weight than the former sub-category.

In NZ Dairy 2 the Commission declined to take the claimed improvement in international competitiveness into account, on the grounds that it had already been accounted for under the payout enhancement benefit. To consider it would therefore amount to double counting. The High Court disagreed, holding that an improvement in international competitiveness was a substantial public benefit. Although it could not be measured in monetary terms because that would risk double counting, it indicated that it should still be identified and given weight. The High Court overturned the Commission's decision to decline authorisation, holding that the benefits substantially outweighed the detriments. The increased weighting given to international competitiveness benefits was one reason for this change. In the later case of Kiwi, the Commission accepted the view of the High Court that such benefits should be given weight. Nevertheless, difficulty proving the causal nexus between the benefit and the acquisition suggests that the weight accorded to it was only limited.

Whakatu and Consortium concerned agreements to close meatworks. Without such agreements to significantly reduce capacity, it was said that meat producers and processors would not be in a state to strengthen their position in international markets. This argument was particularly convincing to the Commission in both

WKHUH LV QR UHTXLUHPHQW WKDW EHQHILWV EH SDVVHG RQ WR FRQVXPHUV )LVKHU 3D\NHO +& DW 1= 'DLU\ +& DW )RU D GLVFXVVLRQ RI ZKHWKHU WKLV UHPDLQV WKH ODZ VHH DERYH IRRWQRWH

1= 'DLU\ DW > @ 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ LQGLFDWHG WKDW ZKLOVW WKH DJUHHPHQW ZRXOG UHVXOW LQ FRVW VDYLQJV LW ZRXOG QRW DOWHU WKH JURVV H[SRUW UHWXUQV WR WKH 1HZ =HDODQG HFRQRP\ 7KH QHW UHYHQXH SD\RXW WR VKDUHKROGHUV ZRXOG LQFUHDVH EXW WKDW ZDV VHSDUDWH IURP LQWHUQDWLRQDO FRPSHWLWLYHQHVV

,ELG DW > @

1= 'DLU\ +& DW

,ELG DW

,ELG

7KH RWKHU ZDV DQ LQFUHDVHG ZHLJKWLQJ JLYHQ WR SD\RXW HQKDQFHPHQW 1= 'DLU\ +& DW 1RWH DOVR WKDW WHQ GD\V DIWHU WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V UHDVRQV ZHUH GHOLYHUHG WKH 0LQLVWHU RI &RPPHUFH FRQYH\HG D VWDWHPHQW RI HFRQRPLF SROLF\ XQGHU V RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW VXSSRUWLQJ UDWLRQDOLVDWLRQ LQ WKH GDLU\ SURFHVVLQJ LQGXVWU\ 1= 'DLU\ +& DW 7KLV LV DOVR OLNHO\ WR KDYH LPSDFWHG RQ WKH +LJK &RXUW·V ILQDO GHFLVLRQ

7KLV DSSHDUV WR EH WKH HIIHFW RI .LZL DW > @ > @

,ELG DW > @ 7KHUH ZHUH VHYHUDO VWHSV WR DFKLHYLQJ DQ LQFUHDVH LQ H[SRUW UHYHQXHV

cases. In Consortium, the public benefit attributed to the improvement in international competitiveness was of greater magnitude than that attributed to the productive efficiency gain. However, in both cases the competitive detriments were limited, making it difficult to gauge the significance of the international competitiveness benefit.

An improvement in international competitiveness was raised by the applicant in Carter Holt, but not discussed by the Commission. Whilst improvements in international competitiveness were accepted in Fletcher Challenge and Qantas (HC), there was no discussion of the weight to be attached to them. This lack of discussion suggests that no, or very little, weight was accorded to the international competitiveness benefit in these decisions.

Lack of evidence of the extent of the international competitiveness benefit was the reason it was not accepted in Forest Products, Amcor and Tasman. As discussed above, proving an enhancement in international competitiveness is probably more difficult than proving an enhancement in exports, because the former is more amorphous than the latter.

Conclusion on the weight attached to Category 4 benefits

The Commission has certainly shown itself willing to place real weight on benefits within this category. They have been identified as constituting the main benefit in four decisions, and being substantial in another decision. On occasions where little weight has been placed on them, reasons other than their degree of tangibility are to blame. In particular, the claims are often quite indirectly related to the proposed activities. Where there is a large number of channels through which the activity's consequences must flow before the benefit arises, it is difficult to

:KDNDWX DW > @ &RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @

&RQVRUWLXP DW > @ 1RWH WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ PD\ KDYH EHHQ ORRNLQJ EH\RQG MXVW WKH LQWHUQDWLRQDO FRPSHWLWLYHQHVV LPSURYHPHQWV VHH &RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @

:KDNDWX DW > @ &RQVRUWLXP DW > @

&DUWHU +ROW DW > @

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @

)RUHVW 3URGXFWV DW > @ $PFRU DW > @ 7DVPDQ DW > @

$PFRU DW > @ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ > @ > @ :KDNDWX DW > @ &RQVRUWLXP DW > @ > @

1= 'DLU\ +& DW

7KH OLQN ZDV YHU\ IDU IHWFKHG LQ 1=5)8 DQG 1=5)8 LQ SDUWLFXODU ,Q WKRVH FDVHV LW ZDV FODLPHG WKDW 1HZ =HDODQG·V VXFFHVV RQ WKH UXJE\ ILHOG ZRXOG WUDQVODWH LQWR PRUH WRXULVWV FRPLQJ WR

1HZ =HDODQG 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @

demonstrate the causal nexus. Unlike the first two categories of benefits, this indirect nature is not characteristic of all benefits within this category. It is possible that the link between the benefit and the activity can be reasonably direct. Hence it is not the degree of tangibility of these benefits that causes the problem of proving the causal nexus.

Interestingly, the Commission appears to place more weight on enhanced export opportunities than improvements in international competitiveness. This is largely because of evidential issues. International competitiveness is a much more amorphous concept than export enhancement, and will often be claimed if it is not possible to prove the latter benefit.

An examination of the decisions reveals that the Commission and courts are reluctant to attach more than a negligible weighting to benefits within Categories 1 and 2. They show much greater willingness to place real weight on benefits in Categories 3 and 4. Because the former categories are less tangible than the latter, this prima facie suggests that intangible benefits have less influence on the authorisation decision.

However, as discussed above, there may be alternative explanations for this lower weighting given to intangibles; namely difficulties of proving a causal nexus between the activity seeking to be authorised and the benefit, and difficulties in proving the extent of the benefit. Interestingly, it is these very features that characterise benefits as intangibles. As discussed in Section 1.4, the Chief Economist of the Commerce Commission, Dr Michael Pickford, notes that intangibles usually share two common features; they are difficult to describe precisely and there is no obvious framework in which to assess their value. The former makes it problematic to prove a causal nexus between the benefit and the activity seeking to

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ LQ UHODWLRQ WR WRXULVP EHQHILWV

7KLV PD\ PDNH WKH IUDPLQJ RI WKH EHQHILW LPSRUWDQW H[DFWO\ WKH VDPH EHQHILW PD\ EH PDGH WR DSSHDU PRUH WDQJLEOH VLPSO\ E\ WKH ZD\ WKH DSSOLFDQW H[SUHVVHV LW LQ WKHLU VXEPLVVLRQV +RZHYHU DW OHDVW WKHRUHWLFDOO\ WKH &RPPLVVLRQ VKRXOG EH DEOH WR VHH WKURXJK WKLV ,I WKHUH LV QR HYLGHQFH RI H[SRUW HQKDQFHPHQW WKHUH VHHPV OLWWOH XVH RI DQ DSSOLFDQW FODLPLQJ LW

6HH 3LFNIRUG DW

be authorised, and the latter makes it difficult to prove the extent of their value. Because it is the intangibility that lies at the heart of the problem of proof, it is the intangibility that causes intangible benefits to be given less weight. Hence, it can be concluded that the reason the Commission accords a lower weighting to intangible benefits is because of their inherent difficulty of quantification.

2.3 Contrasting the treatment of quantified intangibles and unquantified intangibles

The Commission and courts have stressed the desirability of quantifying benefits where possible. This could mean that benefits that are not quantified are not given as much weight in the public benefit analysis. Dr Michael Pickford acknowledges this possibility, stating that “it is probably fair to say that, in the absence of quantification, the Commission will need some fairly convincing evidence that they will eventuate before much weight is given to them”. The High Court decision in Qantas (HC) refutes the idea that a benefit could be given less weight simply because it has not been quantified. However, the High Court's position is not necessarily at odds with Pickford's; Pickford leaves open the possibility that unquantified intangible benefits may be accorded real weight, and the High Court says nothing to cast doubt upon the heavy burden of proof that the applicant bears in relation to intangible benefits.

A good illustration of the possibility that unquantified intangibles may not be treated as favourably as quantified intangibles, is provided by the Powerco decision. No more than a minimal weighting has ever been accorded to unquantified Category 2 intangible benefits. However, in Powerco, the Commission took a more quantitative approach to the social detriments arising from redundancies. Although

,I D EHQHILW LV GLIILFXOW HYHQ WR GHVFULEH ZLWK DQ\ SUHFLVLRQ SURYLQJ D FDXVDO QH[XV ZLOO EH SUREOHPDWLF

,I WKHUH LV QR REYLRXV HFRQRPLF IUDPHZRUN LQ ZKLFK WR DVVHVV WKH YDOXH RI D EHQHILW LW LV GLIILFXOW WR SURYLGH FRQYLQFLQJ HYLGHQFH RI LWV H[WHQW

7KLV LV QRW WR VD\ WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LV DFWLQJ LQFRUUHFWO\ LQ DFFRUGLQJ OHVV ZHLJKW WR LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV 7KH OHJDOLW\ RI WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V WUHDWPHQW RI LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV LV GLVFXVVHG LQ 6HFWLRQ

1DWXUDO *DV DW > @ 1HZFDOO DW > @ 7UDQVSRZHU DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 4DQWDV DW

> @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @ 6HH DOVR &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW 7KLV PRUH TXDQWLWDWLYH DSSURDFK LV LQ UHVSRQVH WR WKH FRPPHQWV RI WKH &RXUW RI $SSHDO LQ 7HOHFRP &$ DW

3LFNIRUG DW

4DQWDV +& DW > @

6HH 6HFWLRQ DERYH

the Commission was concerned with a detriment, rather than a benefit, the same methodology could be applied to social benefits. Whilst the Commission recognised that it was not possible to quantify these detriments with any accuracy, “merely for the purpose of demonstrating the impact they may have on the public benefit assessment”, it came up with a ball-park figure of $500,000 for the detriments. This figure was then weighed against the other quantified benefits and detriments. It represented ten times the value of the other detriments and about 11 to 18 percent of the value of the benefits. Hence, it was a factor that could potentially influence the final outcome. This more favourable treatment of quantified intangibles provides a strong incentive to applicants to attempt to quantify intangible benefits. The possibility of quantification is discussed in more detail in Chapter Four.

2.4 The treatment of intangibles over time

In the 1991 Review of the Commerce Act, the review team noted that because the authorisation test enables an analysis of all benefits and detriments which are of value to the community, it can accommodate changes in community values. The objective of this section is to consider whether the treatment of intangibles has changed over time.

2.4.Ł CATEGORY ŁA: “FEEL-GOOD” BENEFITS

In both Ansett and Qantas, the preservation of Air New Zealand as New Zealand's national flag carrier was claimed as a public benefit. When Ansett was decided in 1996, the Commission seemed to place no weight upon it, but in 2003 when the Qantas decision was delivered, the Commission stated that it had a “non- quantifiable symbolic value”. On appeal, the High Court in Qantas agreed that a

3RZHUFR DW > @ 7R GR WKLV LW DVVXPHG WKDW RQ DYHUDJH WKH VRFLDO FRVW ZDV SHU SHUVRQ PDGH UHGXQGDQW ,I IRU H[DPSOH IRUW\ SHRSOH ZHUH PDGH UHGXQGDQW WKH WRWDO FRVW ZRXOG EH

7KLV DSSHDUHG WR EH URXQGHG RII WR 3RZHUFR DW > @ 6HH 6HFWLRQ IRU DQ HYDOXDWLRQ RI WKLV ´EDOO SDUN ILJXUHµ DSSURDFK WR WKH TXDQWLILFDWLRQ RI EHQHILWV

,ELG DW > @ ,W ZDV GHGXFWHG IURP WKH EHQHILWV DFFUXLQJ IURP UDWLRQDOLVDWLRQ

'HSHQGLQJ ZKLFK ILJXUH ZDV DFFHSWHG DV UHSUHVHQWLQJ WKH SXEOLF EHQHILWV

0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH HW DO DW

$QVHWW DW > @ > @ > @

value should be attached to this benefit. As discussed in Section 2.2.1, it is difficult to gauge with certainty what weight the Commission and High Court attached to it. It may well be that it was given very little weight. Nevertheless, in very similar circumstances, the Commission and High Court were prepared to give a benefit which had not accorded any value seven years earlier, at least some weight.

The precise cause of the Commission's change in approach is not clear. It may be the result of an increased emphasis on fostering New Zealanders' sense of identity. In fact, promoting New Zealanders' identity is one of the current Labour-Progressive Coalition Government's three goals. Arguably, government policy often reflects what is of value to society, and to the extent that it does this, it should be incorporated into the public benefit test.

As discussed in Section 2.2.2, in the three decisions that have discussed environmental benefits, it does not seem that they have ever been assigned any real weight. However, as stated in Section 2.2.2, there may be alternative explanations for this low weighting. Interestingly, in Qantas in 2003, it was the Commission, rather than the applicant, who raised the possibility of environmental benefits. The Commission did not raise the benefit in similar circumstances in Ansett, which was decided in 1996. Nor has it raised them in any other case. Arguably the reduction in road usage and the more efficient use of synfuels which were accepted in Fletcher Challenge and Petroleum Corporation, would have

4DQWDV +& DW > @

'DPH 6LOYLD &DUWZULJKW 6SHHFK IURP WKH 7KURQH 6SHHFK GHOLYHUHG DW WKH 6WDWH 2SHQLQJ RI

3DUOLDPHQW :HOOLQJWRQ 1RYHPEHU +RQ 'U 0LFKDHO &XOOHQ 1=3'

%XGJHW 6WDWHPHQW

7KH &RPPLVVLRQ LQ .LZLIUXLW DW DSSHDUHG WR UHFRJQLVH WKLV ZKHQ LW VDLG WKDW ´>S@XEOLF EHQHILW FRXOG DQG LV OLNHO\ WR LQYROYH VRPH RWKHU YDOLG DQG SURSHU JRYHUQPHQW SROLF\µ $OWKRXJK V RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW UHTXLUHV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ WR KDYH UHJDUG WR WKH HFRQRPLF SROLFLHV RI WKH

*RYHUQPHQW DV FRPPXQLFDWHG LQ ZULWLQJ WR WKH &RPPLVVLRQ E\ WKH 0LQLVWHU ZKHQ DSSO\LQJ WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW WHVW WKLV LV QRW QRU VKRXOG LW EH WKH H[FOXVLYH FKDQQHO RI FRPPXQLFDWLRQ RQ SROLF\ PDWWHUV 2WKHU PLQLVWHULDO VWDWHPHQWV RU HQDFWPHQWV DUH DOVR VRXUFHV RI JXLGDQFH .LZLIUXLW DW

+RZHYHU WKH &RPPLVVLRQ ZLOO QRW VSHFXODWH RQ SROLF\ LW ZLOO RQO\ UHO\ XSRQ DXWKRULWDWLYH JRYHUQPHQW VWDWHPHQWV DV WR WKH IXWXUH .LZLIUXLW DW 7KH +LJK &RXUW DSSURYHG RI WKHVH FRPPHQWV LQ

1= 'DLU\ DW

5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ > @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 4DQWDV +& DW > @

,Q SDUWLFXODU GLIILFXOW\ SURYLQJ D FDXVDO OLQN EHWZHHQ WKH SURSRVHG DFWLYLW\ DQG WKH EHQHILW DQG GLIILFXOW\ SURYLQJ WKH H[WHQW RI WKH EHQHILW 7KHVH GLIILFXOWLHV PD\ EH UHIOHFWLYH RI WKH LQWDQJLEOH QDWXUH RI HQYLURQPHQWDO EHQHILWV

positive effects on the environment. As such, they are similar in character to the reduction in flight numbers in Qantas. However, it was only in their more recent decision in Qantas that the Commission raised the benefit.

The fact that the Commission was prepared to raise the possibility of environmental benefits in Qantas in circumstances where it had not done so before, may be an indication to future applicants that it is now willing to place real weight on environmental outcomes. This could be reflective of society's increased emphasis on environmental quality. Alternatively, it may simply be a signal that the Commission wants all public benefits brought to their attention. Dr Alan Bollard, a former Commission Chairman seems to support the prior view. Writing in 1993 he predicted that there would be a growing emphasis on social impact analysis.

Although there does not appear to be any discernible trend in the treatment of this category of benefits, the current Labour-Progressive Coalition Government's objective of “economic transformation” may assist to predict a future trend. To realise this policy the Government has an objective of growing globally competitive firms. Hence, an enhancement of export opportunities or an improvement in international competitiveness would help achieve the Government's current economic policy. This implies that we should see an increase in the weight accorded to these benefits. However, this assumes that the Government's economic policy has never previously focused upon growing globally competitive firms. This is dubious. In 1995 for example, the National Government had an objective of developing a more “open, internationally competitive enterprise economy”.

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ 3HWUROHXP &RUSRUDWLRQ DW > @ > @

)URP WR

%ROODUG DW

&DUWZULJKW &XOOHQ 1=3'

&XOOHQ 1=3' DW

)RU D GLVFXVVLRQ RI KRZ JRYHUQPHQW SROLF\ FDQ EH UHOHYDQW LQ DQ DXWKRULVDWLRQ GHFLVLRQ VHH DERYH IRRWQRWH 7KH SURPRWLRQ RI H[SRUWV ZDV RQH RI WKH EHQHILWV WKDW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ LQ

.LZLIUXLW JDYH DV DQ H[DPSOH RI D YDOLG DQG SURSHU JRYHUQPHQW SROLF\ WKDW FRXOG EH WDNHQ LQWR DFFRXQW LQ WKH DSSOLFDWLRQ RI WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW WHVW .LZLIUXLW DW

5W +RQ %LOO %LUFK %XGJHW 3ROLF\ 6WDWHPHQW 7KH 7UHDVXU\

KWWS ZZZ WUHDVXU\ JRYW SXEV EPE SROLF\ KWP! DFFHVVHG 6HSWHPEHU

Given the limited discussion of intangibles in the decisions, especially those of the most intangible nature, it is difficult to positively state that intangibles have been accorded more weight in more recent decisions. However, the Commission and High Court decisions in Qantas, suggest that this could be the case. If it is, there is now an increased incentive for applicants to claim that intangible benefits will eventuate.

&DWHJRULHV DQG

C H AP T E R T H R EE

Legal and Policy Perspectives on the Treatment of Intangible Benefits

This Chapter seeks to evaluate whether intangible benefits can be treated differently from tangible benefits under the law as it now stands, and whether they should be considered as a matter of policy.

3. Ł The legality of treating intangible benefits differently

3.Ł.Ł DISREGARDING INTANGIBLE BENEFITS

Although there is no specific direction in the Act that intangible benefits must be taken into account, three factors suggest that they should be. First, in not providing a definition of “public benefit”, Parliament showed its preference for a broad public benefit test, incorporating all benefits, irrespective of their degree of tangibility. Had it wished to do so, it could easily have restricted public benefits to tangible benefits.

Second, the words “public benefit” were taken from the Australian Trade Practices Act 1974, where they had long been given a wide meaning. This shows an intention on the part of the New Zealand Parliament that public benefit be given a wide conception, so as to incorporate intangible considerations, as well as more tangible benefits.

,Q .LZLIUXLW WKH &RPPLVVLRQ QRWHG WKDW 3DUOLDPHQW FRXOG HDVLO\ KDYH FRQILQHG WKH &RPPLVVLRQ·V GHOLEHUDWLRQ WR FRPSHWLWLRQ RU HIILFLHQF\ FRQVLGHUDWLRQV KDG LW VR LQWHQGHG .LZLIUXLW DW > @

7KLV SRLQW ZDV QRWHG LQ .LZLIUXLW DW > @ 7KH +LJK &RXUW RI $XVWUDOLD·V GHFLVLRQ LQ 4XHHQVODQG &R RSHUDWLYH 0LOOLQJ $VVRFLDWLRQ LV DXWKRULW\ IRU WKH SURSRVLWLRQ WKDW WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW FRQFHSW KDV D ZLGH DPELW 4XHHQVODQG &R RSHUDWLYH 0LOOLQJ $VVRFLDWLRQ DW

7KLV LQWHQWLRQ LV VXSSRUWHG E\ WKH FRPPHQWV RI &OLYH 0DWWKHZVRQ D /DERXU 0HPEHU RI 3DUOLDPHQW ZKR VDW RQ WKH &RPPHUFH DQG 0DUNHWLQJ 6HOHFW &RPPLWWHH ZKR FRQVLGHUHG WKH &RPPHUFH %LOO ,Q WKH &RPPHUFH %LOO·V WKLUG UHDGLQJ LQ 3DUOLDPHQW KH DOOXGHG WR WKH IDFW WKDW WHUPV LQ WKH $FW FRXOG EH FODULILHG E\ UHIHUHQFH WR $XVWUDOLDQ SUHFHGHQW &OLYH 0DWWKHZVRQ

1=3'

Finally, the legislature chose the broader goal of effective competition, rather than efficiency, as the objective of the Act. If intangible benefits were to be disregarded, only efficiency factors would be considered as part of the public benefit analysis. Parliament deliberately chose a broad objective for the Act, going beyond simply considering efficiency claims, and so there is a strong argument that “public benefit” should be given a commensurately wide interpretation. Excluding intangible benefits means that non-efficiency benefits would be given no consideration, which seems to be at odds with the chosen objective of the Act.

  1. Ł.2 ACCORDING INTANGIBLE BENEFITS A LOWER WEIGHTING

As discussed in Chapter Two, intangible benefits seem to be accorded less weight than tangible benefits. Whilst there is no indication in the Act that intangible benefits must be given the same weighting as tangible benefits, there is also no suggestion that less weight may be given to intangible benefits. There is no obvious explanation why benefits such as cost savings should be worth inherently more than environmental or health benefits. In the absence of either of the justifications set out below applying, there does not appear to be a legitimate reason for according intangible benefits less weight.

Issues of proof

As discussed in Section 2.2, the lower weighting attached to intangible benefits is often due to problems of proof, especially in relation to the causal nexus and the extent of the benefit. Where this is the case, the Commission and courts are

&RPPHUFH $FW VV $ )RU D GLVFXVVLRQ DERXW WKH DSSURSULDWH JRDO RI FRPSHWLWLRQ ODZ VHH 'RXJODV *UHHU (IILFLHQF\ DQG &RPSHWLWLRQ $OWHUQDWLYH &RPSOHPHQWDU\ RU &RQIOLFWLQJ 2EMHFWLYHV 5HVHDUFK 0RQRJUDSK 1HZ =HDODQG ,QVWLWXWH RI (FRQRPLF 5HVHDUFK :HOOLQJWRQ

6WHSKHQ -HQQLQJV DQG 6XVDQ %HJJ $Q (FRQRPLF 5HYLHZ RI &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ 'HFLVLRQV XQGHU WKH &RPPHUFH $FW 5HSRUW SUHSDUHG IRU WKH 7UHDVXU\ -DUGHQ &R

:HOOLQJWRQ DW

&DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV DUH QRQ HIILFLHQF\ JDLQV DQG WKH RWKHU WKUHH FDWHJRULHV DUH HIILFLHQF\ JDLQV

$Q\ QRQ HIILFLHQF\ JDLQV IDOOLQJ RXWVLGH &DWHJRU\ DUH OLNHO\ WR EH LQWDQJLEOH LQ QDWXUH +HQFH E\ H[FOXGLQJ LQWDQJLEOHV IURP WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW DQDO\VLV QRQ HIILFLHQF\ JDLQV ZLOO QRW EH FRQVLGHUHG 2EYLRXVO\ VRPH HIILFLHQF\ JDLQV ZLOO DOVR QRW EH FRQVLGHUHG

&HWHULV SDULEXV RI FRXUVH

1RWH WKDW LW PD\ EH WKDW WKH YHU\ LQWDQJLELOLW\ RI WKH EHQHILW JLYHV ULVH WR WKH SUREOHP RI SURRI

entirely justified in placing less weight on intangible benefits because the applicant bears the burden of proving these matters.

The scheme of the Act

The lesser weighting given to intangibles, may be partially justified by the scheme of the Act. Section 3A of the Act was inserted in 1990 and requires the Commission to have regard to any efficiencies that will, or will be likely to result, from the conduct seeking to be authorised. It is the only direct assistance that the Act gives in relation to the application of the public benefit test. Although the Commission and courts appear to have assumed that section 3A places the focus on efficiency benefits, it is not entirely clear that this is the effect or intention of the provision.

Taken literally, section 3A is simply a reminder to the Commission and courts that they must consider efficiency benefits. At the very most, it places a positive obligation upon the Commission to consider efficiencies. The High Court in Telecom (HC) seemed to recognise this, noting that efficiencies were neither the only, nor the most important consideration. In the 1992 Review of the Commerce Act the review team acknowledged that section 3A did not clearly establish efficiencies as the principal benefit. It was for that reason that the majority of the review team recommended the amendment of section 3A to state that efficiencies were the principal consideration in the authorisation process. However, this recommendation was never implemented. Arguably this means that,

)RU H[DPSOH VHH :KDNDWX DW > @

7HOHFRP +& DW

%ULHUOH\ DW > @ 0LGODQG +HDOWK DW > @ > @ $QVHWW DW > @ 5DYHQVGRZQ DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 3RZHUFR DW > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @

> @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ 7KLV SRVLWLRQ LV DOVR VXSSRUWHG E\ WKH &KLHI (FRQRPLVW RI WKH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG 3LFNIRUG DW

8QIRUWXQDWHO\ +DQVDUG LV RI OLWWOH DVVLVWDQFH

,Q RWKHU ZRUGV LW VLPSO\ PDNHV H[SOLFLW ZKDW KDG DOZD\V EHHQ LPSOLFLW

5H[ $KGDU ´7KH $XWKRULVDWLRQ 3URFHVV DQG WKH ´3XEOLF %HQHILWµ 7HVWµ LQ 5H[ $KGDU HG

&RPSHWLWLRQ /DZ DQG 3ROLF\ LQ 1HZ =HDODQG 7KH /DZ %RRN &RPSDQ\ 6\GQH\ DW 0U 3KLOLS %XUGRQ WKH 1DWLRQDO 0HPEHU RI 3DUOLDPHQW IRU )HQGDOWRQ UHFRJQLVHG WKLV SRVLWLYH REOLJDWLRQ LQ WKH %LOO·V ILUVW UHDGLQJ QRWLQJ WKDW LW ´VSHFLILFDOO\ UHTXLUHV HIILFLHQFLHV WR EH XVHG DV RQH RI WKH FULWHULD WR EH WDNHQ LQWR FRQVLGHUDWLRQ ZKHQ WHVWLQJ WKH PHULWV RI D SURSRVHG PHUJHU DQG RU WDNHRYHUµ 3KLOLS %XUGRQ 1=3' 5HSRUW RI WKH &RPPHUFH DQG 0DUNHWLQJ &RPPLWWHH $VLGH IURP WKLV FRPPHQW +DQVDUG LV RI QR DVVLVWDQFH

7HOHFRP +& DW $OWKRXJK LQ WKH FDVH RI D PHUJHU WKH &RXUW QRWHG WKDW HIILFLHQF\ FRQVLGHUDWLRQV SRVLWLYH DQG QHJDWLYH ZRXOG EH WKH SULPH FRQVLGHUDWLRQ

0LQLVWU\ RI &RPPHUFH HW DO DW > @

,ELG DW > @ > @ > @ > @

ceteris paribus, efficiency benefits should be given no greater weight than non- efficiency benefits.

Even if section 3A could be said to justify greater weight being placed on efficiency benefits, this only provides a justification for lesser weight being placed upon intangible benefits within Category 1. The other categories all represent efficiency gains. Hence this justification can only provide a partial explanation, if any explanation, for the lower weighting accorded to intangible benefits.

3.2 Disregarding intangible benefits as a matter of policy

A potential advantage of restricting the notion of “public benefit” to tangible benefits is that it limits the ambit of the investigation, reducing the time and cost involved in making a decision. Because intangible benefits do not appear to have affected the outcome of cases to date, disregarding them will only make a difference in extremely rare cases (if ever). However, this argument ignores the definitional issue that such a change will create. Currently it is not necessary for applicants to characterise benefits as tangible or intangible; they can simply list all the benefits that they claim will arise as a result of the activity that is sought to be authorised. If public benefits were to be restricted to tangible benefits, the definitional issue discussed in Chapter One would arise. Arguments would be made about whether a particular benefit was a tangible or intangible benefit. This would increase the cost and time involved in the decision making process, and at least partially, if not wholly, offset the time and cost savings that would arise from not

+RZHYHU LW VKRXOG EH QRWHG WKDW WKH HIILFLHQF\ EHQHILWV DULVLQJ IURP D SURSRVHG DFWLYLW\ ZLOO XVXDOO\ EH DFFRUGHG WKH JUHDWHVW ZHLJKW EHFDXVH WKH\ WHQG WR EH RI WKH JUHDWHVW PDJQLWXGH

,Q UHVSHFW RI &DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV VHH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW ,W LV VWDWHG WKDW

´RWKHU IDFWRUV VXFK DV HQYLURQPHQWDO DQG VRFLDO IDFWRUV ´LQWDQJLEOHµ IDFWRUV FDQ DW OHDVW FRQFHSWXDOO\ EH LQFOXGHG ZLWKLQ DQ HIILFLHQF\ SHUVSHFWLYHµ &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

7KH 5HYLHZ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW UHFRPPHQGHG D UHVWULFWLRQ XSRQ WKH FRQFHSW RI SXEOLF EHQHILW WR HFRQRPLF EHQHILWV 'HSDUWPHQW RI 7UDGH DQG ,QGXVWU\ $ 'LVFXVVLRQ 3DSHU 5HYLHZ RI WKH &RPPHUFH $FW 'HSDUWPHQW RI 7UDGH DQG ,QGXVWU\ :HOOLQJWRQ DW ,W ZDV KRSHG WKDW VXFK D UHVWULFWLRQ ZRXOG UHGXFH WKH DPELW RI WKH LQYHVWLJDWLRQ DQG VSHHG XS WKH ZKROH DXWKRULVDWLRQ SURFHVV

7KLV GHILQLWLRQDO SUREOHP ZDV QRWHG E\ 'U $ODQ %ROODUG LQ FRQVLGHULQJ ZKHWKHU WKH SXEOLF EHQHILW WHVW VKRXOG EH UHVWULFWHG WR HFRQRPLF EHQHILWV DQG GHWULPHQWV +H QRWHG WKDW VXFK D UHVWULFWLRQ ZRXOG PDNH LW GLIILFXOW WR MXGJH ZKHWKHU FHUWDLQ LVVXHV OLNH XQHPSOR\PHQW ZRXOG TXDOLI\ DV

´HFRQRPLFµ RU QRW $ODQ %ROODUG $Q (FRQRPLF &RPPHQW RQ WKH &RPPHUFH $FW 5HYLHZ 1HZ =HDODQG

,QVWLWXWH RI (FRQRPLF 5HVHDUFK :HOOLQJWRQ DW

2EYLRXVO\ WKH DSSOLFDQW PXVW DOVR SURYLGH HYLGHQFH WR VXSSRUW WKH FODLPHG EHQHILWV

having to evaluate the weighting to be given to intangible benefits. Furthermore, inconsistencies could arise between cases. A particular benefit may be treated as a tangible benefit in one case and so be considered as part of the public benefit test, but be treated as an intangible benefit in another case and so not be considered. This would increase uncertainty in the authorisation area.

Moreover, there does not appear to be any sensible policy reason for excluding intangible benefits from the public benefit test. Environmental and health benefits are valuable, particularly in today's society. The current Government's objective of promoting New Zealand's identity suggests that even the most intangible benefits, those falling within Category 1, have at least some value in today's society.

7KH LQFUHDVHG FRVWV PD\ HYHQ PRUH WKDQ RIIVHW WKHVH WLPH DQG FRVW VDYLQJV

&DUWZULJKW &XOOHQ 1=3' DW

C H AP T E R F 0 U R

Quantification of Intangible Benefits

As concluded in Section 2.3, because quantified intangibles may be given more weight than their unquantified counterparts, there is an incentive for applicants to attempt to quantify intangible benefits. This Chapter seeks to examine the desirability and feasibility of quantifying intangible benefits.

4. Ł The desirability of quantifying intangible benefits

In the only authorisation decision ever to reach the Court of Appeal, Richardson J stressed the desirability of quantifying benefits and detriments, where and to the extent that it is feasible. He noted the “responsibility on a regulatory body to attempt so far as possible to quantify detriments and benefits rather than rely on a purely intuitive judgment”. In its last eight decisions, the Commission has remarked that it is mindful of this responsibility. This section seeks to evaluate the desirability of such a “responsibility”, with reference to intangible benefits.

4.Ł.Ł THE ADVANTAGES OF QUANTIFYING INTANGIBLE BENEFITS

The quantification of benefits and detriments is a process designed to inform the Commission of the possible magnitudes of the various elements, and thereby assist it in the application of its judgment. Because all the benefits and detriments are in a common unit of measurement, it is much easier to apply the public benefit test; the quantified benefits simply need to be weighed against the quantified detriments to give an estimate of the net benefit or detriment arising from the activity that is sought to be authorised. Quantification provides a more objective framework within

7HOHFRP &$ DW

,ELG 7KH +LJK &RXUW LQ WKHLU UHFHQW GHFLVLRQ LQ 4DQWDV DOVR QRWHG WKLV UHVSRQVLELOLW\ 4DQWDV +&

DW > @

1HZFDOO DW > @ 7UDQVSRZHU DW > @ 7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ (OHFWULFLW\

*RYHUQDQFH DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ )RU RWKHU VWDWHPHQWV DERXW WKH GHVLUDELOLW\ RI TXDQWLILFDWLRQ VHH 1DWXUDO *DV DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 3RZHUFR DW > @

5XDSHKX DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ 6HH DOVR &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

(OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 6HH DOVR &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ DW

which to establish the weights to be given to the various benefits and detriments claimed, and so results in a more transparent decision making process.

The Commission in NZRFU 2 suggested that the problem with relying solely on qualitative arguments is that reasonable arguments can be put forward by different parties that come to different conclusions about the desirability of a course of action. However, the same can be said of quantitative arguments; different groups will arrive at different valuations for intangible benefits, owing to the different assumptions that they make. For example, in Qantas the applicants submitted that travellers would receive a 100 percent convenience gain from improved aircraft schedules, resulting in a benefit of $2 million annually from year three onwards. The Commission was sceptical of the 100 percent gain, questioning whether people completely waste their time and suggesting that they find other less optimal ways to use it. In the end, the Commission held that travellers would only achieve a 20 percent convenience gain, and so the benefit would amount to $476,000. This only represents 23.8 percent of the value claimed by Qantas and Air New Zealand.

4.Ł.2 THE PROBLEMS ASSOCIATED WITH QUANTIFYING INTANGIBLE BENEFITS

There are two basic issues associated with the quantification of intangible benefits which may make their quantification impractical: reliability and cost.

Reliability issues

The very nature of intangible benefits means that they are inherently difficult to quantify. Hence, when they are quantified a number of simplifying and often unrealistic assumptions must be made, making the reliability of the calculations

(OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW > @

3URYLGHG WKH DVVXPSWLRQV UHOLHG XSRQ DQG WKH SURFHVV RI TXDQWLILFDWLRQ DUH VHW RXW LQ GHWDLO ,W KDV EHHQ VXJJHVWHG WKDW DXWKRULVDWLRQ GHFLVLRQV JDLQ D JUHDWHU OHJLWLPDF\ WKURXJK WKH GLVFLSOLQH DQG WUDQVSDUHQF\ RI TXDQWLWDWLYH DVVHVVPHQW $OODQ )HOV DQG 7LP *ULPZDGH ´$XWKRULVDWLRQ ,V LW 6WLOO 5HOHYDQW WR $XVWUDOLDQ &RPSHWLWLRQ /DZ"µ &RPSHWLWLRQ DQG &RQVXPHU /DZ -RXUQDO DW

1=5)8 DW > @

4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ 1RWH WKDW WKH EHQHILW ZDV VDLG WR EH KLJKHU LQ WKH ILUVW DQG VHFRQG \HDUV PLOOLRQ LQ WKH ILUVW \HDU DQG PLOOLRQ LQ WKH VHFRQG \HDU

,ELG DW > @

,ELG DW > @ > @ )RU RWKHU H[DPSOHV VHH 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ (OHFWULFLW\ *RYHUQDQFH DW

> @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 1=5)8 > @ > @ > @ > @

doubtful. If it is not possible to quantify benefits with any degree of accuracy, their inclusion in the quantitative analysis may be more misleading than helpful. It may detract from the quality of the decision, and result in some practices being authorised when they should not be and some not being authorised when they should be.

The number of assumptions that need to be made in quantifying intangible benefits gives Commissioners greater scope to endorse or reject techniques depending on their economic inclination. Where this occurs a biased outcome is produced, which may not accurately reflect the value of the benefit. It also reduces the degree of consistency between cases. It is important to note that this same bias could exist in the weight given to unquantified intangible benefits. However, the bias will be more evident in the case of quantified intangibles because the decision making process is more transparent. This transparency may actually serve to reduce the bias, and so quantification may actually reduce the scope for Commissioners to impose their own biases upon decisions.

There are a number of ways to minimise this reliability concern. Wider ranges of values for benefits can be used to reduce the potential margin for error. The weight given to the benefit can be reduced to ensure that it does not improperly cause the activity to be authorised. Finally, the inclusion of a qualitative evaluation of the benefit can either confirm or refute the quantitative assessment.

Cost issues

The legal and economic fees incurred by parties seeking authorisation are considerable. If intangible benefits were to be quantified on a regular basis, the

7KH 7UHDVXU\ &RVW %HQHILW $QDO\VLV 3ULPHU 7KH 7UHDVXU\ :HOOLQJWRQ DW

5XDSHKX DW > @ 6HQVLWLYLW\ DQDO\VLV RI WKH EHQHILW WR NH\ YDULDEOHV FDQ EH SDUWLFXODUO\ KHOSIXO 6HQVLWLYLW\ DQDO\VLV LV D PHWKRG RI DVVHVVLQJ WKH UREXVWQHVV RI UHVXOWV WR FKDQJHV LQ WKH SDUDPHWHUV

VHH 'DYLG $QGHUVRQ 'HQQLV 6ZHHQH\ DQG 7KRPDV :LOOLDPV 4XDQWLWDWLYH 0HWKRGV IRU %XVLQHVV

WK HG 7KRPVRQ 6RXWK :HVWHUQ %HOPRQW DW *LYLQJ D EHQHILW D ZLGHU UDQJH RI YDOXHV PD\ MXVW SRVWSRQH WKH LQHYLWDEOH EHFDXVH DW VRPH VWDJH LW ZLOO QHHG WR EH ZHLJKHG DORQJVLGH WKH RWKHU EHQHILWV DJDLQVW WKH GHWULPHQWV DQG VR D PRUH GHILQLWLYH YDOXH ZLOO QHHG WR EH SODFHG XSRQ LW

4DQWDV +& DW > @ 1RWH WKDW WKLV PD\ DFWXDOO\ UHGXFH WKH DFFXUDF\ RI WKH DXWKRULVDWLRQ GHFLVLRQ DQG FUHDWH D ELDV DJDLQVW DXWKRULVDWLRQ

)RU H[DPSOH -HQQLQJV DQG %HJJ KDYH HVWLPDWHG WKDW WKH OHJDO DQG HFRQRPLF FRVWV LQFXUUHG E\ WKH DSSOLFDQWV LQ *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU ZHUH PLOOLRQ -HQQLQJV DQG %HJJ DW *LYHQ WKDW WKLV FDVH ZDV GHFLGHG \HDUV DJR WKH FRVWV DUH OLNHO\ WR EH VLJQLILFDQWO\ KLJKHU WRGD\ 3URIHVVRU 7LP +D]OHGLQH RI WKH (FRQRPLFV 'HSDUWPHQW DW WKH 8QLYHUVLW\ RI $XFNODQG VXJJHVWV WKDW WKH DLUOLQHV LQ 4DQWDV SUREDEO\ VSHQW DURXQG PLOOLRQ LQ OHJDO DQG FRQVXOWDQF\ IHHV 7LP +D]OHGLQH

expense would increase even further, because the methodologies used to quantify intangible benefits tend to be resource intensive.

The Commission relies heavily upon applicants to provide evidence of the extent of the public benefits. Applicants have no incentive to quantify benefits if the cost of quantification is greater than the benefit arising from the increased likelihood that the activity will be authorised.

Furthermore, there is no point in the Commission insisting upon quantification if the cost of quantification would outweigh the benefit to society from the improvement in decision making. That this might occur was recognised by the Commission in Newcall. In relation to the quantification of benefits, Professor Ergas on behalf of Telecom wondered whether the cost of their quantification would be such that they would “greatly swamp any benefits that it might provide you with in terms of improved decision-making”. The Commission acknowledged that in that instance it would have been very difficult and costly to undertake quantification with any precision.

4.Ł.3 CONCLUSION

Whilst the quantification of intangible benefits is of significant assistance to the Commission if it is accurate, the nature of intangible benefits may mean that quantification is too unreliable and costly to render it feasible. Where this is the case, qualitative assessment has an important role to play. The next three sections present three alternative methods of quantifying intangible benefits.

4.2 Quantification with an economic model

It may be possible to utilise an existing economic model or to develop a new one, to quantify the magnitude of a benefit. Such models can be partial equilibrium or general equilibrium. Partial equilibrium models analyse the changes in welfare by

´$SSOLFDWLRQ RI WKH 3XELF %HQHILW 7HVW WR WKH $LU 1HZ =HDODQG 4DQWDV &DVHµ 1HZ

=HDODQG (FRQRPLFV 3DSHU DW

1HZFDOO DW > @

,ELG DW > @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @ (OHFWULFLW\

*RYHUQDQFH DW > @ > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 4DQWDV

+& DW > @ > @

focusing upon a particular market, whereas general equilibrium models take a much broader approach, looking at the effects on the entire economy.

Partial equilibrium analysis can be used where the intangible benefit arises in a market context. Theoretically, where a market exists, the elasticities of the demand and supply curves can be estimated. The elasticity of the relevant curve can be used in conjunction with the change in price or quantity to give an estimate of the value of the benefit to society, as measured by the change in consumer or producer surplus.

Critique of the approach

Partial equilibrium analysis requires an estimate of the elasticity of demand or supply to be made. This is often not an easy task. However, the elasticity of demand for the particular good or service is almost always estimated to quantify the allocative efficiency detriment. Hence, in the case of quality improvements the elasticity will have already been estimated. For other benefits, such as increased tourism and exports, existing studies may be available to minimise the cost and time involved in calculating the elasticity value.

&DUROLQH 'LQZLGG\ DQG )UDQFLV 7HDO 7KH 7ZR 6HFWRU *HQHUDO (TXLOLEULXP 0RGHO $ 1HZ $SSURDFK

3KLOLS $ODQ 3XEOLVKHUV 1HZ <RUN DW 3DXO .UXJPDQ DQG 0DXULFH 2EVWIHOG

,QWHUQDWLRQDO (FRQRPLFV 7KHRU\ DQG 3ROLF\ WK HG 3HDUVRQ $GGLVRQ :HVOH\ %RVWRQ DW 3DUWLDO HTXLOLEULXP DQDO\VLV XWLOLVHV D FRQYHQWLRQDO VXSSO\ DQG GHPDQG PRGHO ZKHUHDV JHQHUDO HTXLOLEULXP DQDO\VLV XVHV D PXFK PRUH FRPSOH[ PRGHO FRQVLVWLQJ RI D V\VWHP RI HTXDWLRQV FDSWXULQJ WKH EHKDYLRXU RI ILUPV KRXVHKROGV DQG WKH JRYHUQPHQW DQG KRZ WKHVH VHFWRUV LQWHUDFW

)RU IXUWKHU LQIRUPDWLRQ VHH 'LQZLGG\ DQG 7HDO

%HQHILWV ZLWKLQ &DWHJRULHV DQG DULVH LQ PDUNHWV 7R WKH H[WHQW WKDW &DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV DUH H[WHUQDOLWLHV WKH\ FDQ DOVR EH DQDO\VHG LQ D PDUNHW FRQWH[W )UDQN DQG %HUQDQNH DW

9DULDQ DW

(ODVWLFLW\ LV D PHDVXUH RI WKH UHVSRQVLYHQHVV RI TXDQWLW\ GHPDQGHG RU VXSSOLHG WR FKDQJHV LQ SULFH ,W LV HTXDO WR WKH SHUFHQWDJH FKDQJH LQ TXDQWLW\ GHPDQGHG RU VXSSOLHG IURP D RQH SHUFHQWDJH

FKDQJH LQ SULFH ,ELG DW

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @ )RU DQ H[SODQDWLRQ RI ZKDW FRQVXPHU DQG SURGXFHU VXUSOXV DUH VHH DERYH IRRWQRWHV DQG

7KH HODVWLFLW\ RI GHPDQG LV UHTXLUHG LI WKH FKDQJH LQ FRQVXPHU VXUSOXV LV EHLQJ FDOFXODWHG 7KH HODVWLFLW\ RI VXSSO\ LV UHTXLUHG LI WKH FKDQJH LQ SURGXFHU VXUSOXV LV EHLQJ FDOFXODWHG

:KLFK LV FRPSOLFDWHG IXUWKHU E\ WKH IDFW WKDW HODVWLFLWLHV XVXDOO\ YDU\ DORQJ WKH FXUYH )UDQN DQG

%HUQDQNH DW

$W OHDVW VLQFH WKH GHFLVLRQ RI WKH &RXUW RI $SSHDO LQ 7HOHFRP &$

&DWHJRU\ $

6HH 0XUUD\ 1RUWK 7KH (FRQRPLF 'HWHUPLQDQWV RI 'RPHVWLF 7UDYHO LQ 1HZ =HDODQG 1HZ =HDODQG 7RXULVP DQG 3XEOLFLW\ 'HSDUWPHQW :HOOLQJWRQ $SSHQGL[ 6L[ FDOFXODWHV WKH HODVWLFLW\ RI GHPDQG IRU WRXULVP 1RWH WKDW LQ WKH FDVH RI FDVH RI WRXULVP DQG H[SRUW EHQHILWV WKH UHOHYDQW PDUNHW ZLOO EH GLIIHUHQW WR WKH PDUNHW WKDW LV WKH IRFXV RI WKH FDVH

The usefulness of partial equilibrium analysis may be reduced by the use of inaccurate elasticity values. Elasticity values are calculated by observing the values of price and quantity in a marketplace on more than one occasion. If the relevant curve, or the other intersecting curve, has shifted during the period of observation or since the elasticity value was calculated, then the elasticity value may be inaccurate. Using the wrong elasticity value will give an incorrect valuation of the public benefit.

4.2.2 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS

General equilibrium analysis can be utilised where the relationship between the activity that is sought to be authorised and the benefit is known. In Qantas, the applicants used a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to estimate the benefits to New Zealand from an increase in tourism. Having arrived at an estimate for the increase in tourist numbers, the applicants estimated how much these additional tourists would spend in New Zealand and used CGE modelling to estimate the effect of that spending on the rest of the economy.

Critique of the approach

In Qantas, the Commission indicated that it preferred partial equilibrium analysis to general equilibrium analysis. Because the assessment of competitive detriments is restricted to the immediate market, partial equilibrium analysis must be used to evaluate their magnitude. If general equilibrium analysis is then used to evaluate some or all of the benefits, the estimation methods do not produce comparable values.

To date, no individual or organisation has developed a general equilibrium model of the New Zealand economy. Given the very high fixed costs associated with

)UDQN DQG %HUQDQNH DW

$ &*( PRGHO LV D JHQHUDO HTXLOLEULXP PRGHO ZKLFK LV VROYHG YLD FRPSXWHU VLPXODWLRQ 6XFK PRGHOV DUH DOVR NQRZQ DV DSSOLHG JHQHUDO HTXLOLEULXP $*( PRGHOV

4DQWDV DW > @ > @

,ELG DW > @

,ELG DW > @ 7KH +LJK &RXUW DJUHHG 4DQWDV +& DW > @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH *RRGPDQ )LHOGHU DW > @ $PFRU DW > @ LL

4DQWDV DW > @

,ELG 7KLV SRLQW ZDV HQGRUVHG E\ WKH +LJK &RXUW LQ 4DQWDV +& DW > @

+RZHYHU WKH 1HZ =HDODQG ,QVWLWXWH RI (FRQRPLF 5HVHDUFK ´1=,(5µ LV WU\LQJ WR JHW IXQGLQJ WR GHYHORS RQH ,QWHUYLHZ ZLWK 'U 1LYHQ :LQFKHVWHU 6HSWHPEHU

setting up such a model, developing a general equilibrium model of the New Zealand economy for a competition law case will almost certainly never be viable. Even if such a model was developed by an organisation such as the New Zealand Institute of Economic Research (NZIER), reliability is a concern. General equilibrium modelling relies upon a vast number of assumptions, most of which cannot be determined with any accuracy. In Qantas, Ralph Lattimore suggested that a

SUREOHP WKDW·V SDUWLFXODUO\ DFXWH IRU JHQHUDO HTXLOLEULXP PRGHOV RI WKH 1HZ =HDODQG HFRQRP\ LV WKDW RI WKH KXQGUHGV DQG WKRXVDQGV RI SDUDPHWHUV LQ WKH PRGHO RI WKHP DUH JXHVVWLPDWHV 7KH\ KDYH QHYHU EHHQ HVWLPDWHG LQ D 1HZ =HDODQG PDUNHW HQYLURQPHQW

Hence, even a model specifically designed to replicate the features of the New Zealand economy could be “inapt in many subtle ways, with unknowable consequences for the validity of the results”.

There are some global equilibrium models which are designed to be utilised across a number of countries. Even utilising such an existing model is a major undertaking, entailing significant costs. Less than 10 economists in New Zealand would be able to apply a CGE model to estimate the value of a particular benefit. Furthermore, reliability concerns are even more pronounced for this class of models, because they are not specifically designed to replicate the features of the New Zealand economy. For example, in Qantas the three different models considered all produced vastly different results, with one of the models producing a value double that of another model.

'DWD LV QHHGHG RQ DOO PDUNHWV LQ WKH HFRQRP\ VLPXOWDQHRXVO\

$ VHQLRU IHOORZ DW 1=,(5 ZKR ZHUH HPSOR\HG LQ VXSSRUW RI *XOOLYHU 3DFLILF *URXS·V VXEPLVVLRQ

4DQWDV DW > @

,ELG DW > @ 7KLV PDNHV VHQVLWLYLW\ DQDO\VLV RI SDUWLFXODU LPSRUWDQFH )RU DQ H[SODQDWLRQ RI ZKDW VHQVLWLYLW\ DQDO\VLV LV VHH DERYH IRRWQRWH

)RU H[DPSOH WKH 021$6+ PRGHO ZKLFK ZDV XVHG LQ 4DQWDV DQG WKH *7$3 PRGHO )RU IXUWKHU GHWDLOV DERXW WKH 021$6+ PRGHO VHH 3HWHU 'L[RQ DQG 0DXUHHQ 5LPPHU '\QDPLF *HQHUDO (TXLOLEULXP 0RGHOOLQJ IRU )RUHFDVWLQJ DQG 3ROLF\ $ 3UDFWLFDO *XLGH DQG 'RFXPHQWDWLRQ RI 021$6+

1RUWK +ROODQG $PVWHUGDP )RU IXUWKHU GHWDLOV DERXW WKH *7$3 PRGHO VHH 7KRPDV +HUWHO

HG *OREDO 7UDGH $QDO\VLV 0RGHOLQJ DQG $SSOLFDWLRQV &DPEULGJH 8QLYHUVLW\ 3UHVV 1HZ <RUN

$V ZDV WKH FDVH LQ 4DQWDV

,QWHUYLHZ ZLWK 'U 1LYHQ :LQFKHVWHU 6HSWHPEHU

4DQWDV DW > @ 7KH PRGHOV SURGXFHG YDOXHV RI PLOOLRQ PLOOLRQ DQG PLOOLRQ 7KLV FRPSOH[LW\ OHG WKH &RPPLVVLRQ WR DGRSW D FDXWLRXV DSSURDFK ZKHQ FRQVLGHULQJ WKHLU UHVXOWV

4DQWDV DW > @

4.3 The “willingness to pay” approach

Because all public benefits must accrue to someone, in principle a valuation can be obtained by ascertaining how much the beneficiaries would be willing to pay for the benefit. There are two ways to arrive at willingness to pay values. A contingent valuation asks beneficiaries the maximum amount that they would be prepared to pay to receive the benefit. An observational valuation observes the behaviour of individuals in markets where the benefit has an influence.

In theory, willingness to pay provides an economic framework in which to value intangible benefits. However, in practice it is very difficult to calculate willingness to pay values. It is often difficult to obtain accurate answers from respondents of the maximum amount that they would be prepared to pay for the benefit, because they have difficulty conceptualising and isolating the benefit, or they figure that they can free ride on the payments of others. It is also difficult to arrive at willingness to pay values via market based studies, because there are usually a number of influences on the price of the product or service, aside from the benefit being examined. These influences must be isolated before a value for the benefit can be calculated. The willingness to pay technique and the problems associated with it are discussed further below, in the context of valuing public safety benefits.

$ ZLOOLQJQHVV WR DFFHSW DSSURDFK FRXOG DOVR EH XWLOLVHG WR HYDOXDWH SXEOLF EHQHILWV 7KLV DSSURDFK IRFXVHV XSRQ KRZ PXFK LQGLYLGXDOV ZRXOG QHHG WR EH SDLG WR FRPSHQVDWH WKHP IRU JLYLQJ XS D FHUWDLQ EHQHILW -DJDGLVK *XULD HW DO 7KH 1HZ =HDODQG 9DOXHV RI 6WDWLVWLFDO /LIH DQG RI WKH

3UHYHQWLRQ RI ,QMXULHV 'UDIW 5HSRUW DW 7KH WZR PHWKRGV RIWHQ GHULYH GLIIHUHQW UHVXOWV )RU DQ H[SODQDWLRQ RI ZK\ VHH *XULD HW DO DW

*LVHOD .REHOW +HDOWK (FRQRPLFV $Q ,QWURGXFWLRQ WR (FRQRPLF (YDOXDWLRQ 2IILFH RI +HDOWK

(FRQRPLFV /RQGRQ DW 7KH 7UHDVXU\ DW 7KLV PHWKRG XVHV ´VWDWHG SUHIHUHQFHVµ

´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU 7KH (FRQRPLVW DW 7KH 7UHDVXU\ DW 7KLV XVHV PHWKRG ´UHYHDOHG SUHIHUHQFHVµ )RU H[DPSOH LQ WKH FRQWH[W RI PRUWDOLW\ DQG PRUELGLW\ YDOXDWLRQ ZDJHV FRXOG EH VWXGLHG ,Q WKHRU\ ZRUNHUV LQ GDQJHURXV MREV VKRXOG EH SDLG D SUHPLXP WR FRPSHQVDWH WKHP IRU WKH JUHDWHU FKDQFH RI GHDWK DQG LQMXU\

0DUN *RRGFKLOG .HO 6DQGHUVRQ DQG *DQHVK 1DQD 0HDVXULQJ WKH 7RWDO &RVW RI ,QMXU\ LQ 1HZ

=HDODQG $ 5HYLHZ RI $OWHUQDWLYH &RVW 0HWKRGRORJLHV 5HSRUW SUHSDUHG IRU WKH 'HSDUWPHQW RI /DERXU

%XVLQHVV DQG (FRQRPLF 5HVHDUFK :HOOLQJWRQ DW 7KLV LV SDUWLFXODUO\ VR IRU WKH PRVW LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV &DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV

$QG WKHUHE\ JHW WKH EHQHILW IRU IUHH 7KLV LV HVSHFLDOO\ VR IRU &DWHJRU\ DQG EHQHILWV

´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW

4.3.2 AN APPLIED EXAMPLE: VALUING PUBLIC SAFETY BENEFITS

Public safety is a benefit which has been claimed in four decisions, but as yet, no attempt has been made to quantify it. Whilst it is uncontroversial that an increase in public safety is a benefit, it is not so easy to quantify it. The purpose of this subsection is to use public safety as a case study of whether some of the more intangible benefits can be quantified.

From a purely theoretical perspective, the valuation of public safety seems quite straightforward. The increase in safety, measured in terms of the numbers of deaths and injuries prevented, simply needs to be multiplied by the monetary value of preventing these fatalities and casualties, to give the benefit attributable to public safety. However, in practice the calculation of the values of these two inputs is problematic. Techniques for calculating these values are discussed below.

Techniques for the calculation of the impact of improved safety on the number of casualties and fatalities

A number of studies consider an initiative to improve public safety and convert it into the number of fatalities or injuries avoided. Where a relevant study is available, it can be used to calculate the health outcomes from the activity that is sought to be authorised, in terms of fatalities and injuries avoided.

Where individuals are not injured or killed, but their quality of life is adversely affected, this can be converted into a measure of life years lost using cost utility

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ > @ 1DWXUDO *DV :DLNDWR > @ 6SHHGZD\ DW > @ > @ 4DQWDV LQ > @ 1RWH WKDW LW ZDV WKH &RPPLVVLRQ UDWKHU WKDQ WKH DSSOLFDQW WKDW LGHQWLILHG WKH EHQHILW LQ 4DQWDV

/DQG 7UDQVSRUW 1HZ =HDODQG 3XWWLQJ D 3ULFH RQ /LIH /DQG 7UDQVSRUW 1HZ =HDODQG

KWWS ZZZ ODQGWUDQVSRUW JRYW Q] SXEOLFDWLRQV UVQ] PDU KWPO! DFFHVVHG $XJXVW

-XVW OLNH DQ\ RWKHU JRRG RU VHUYLFH SXEOLF VDIHW\ FRPSHWHV IRU SHRSOHV· UHVRXUFHV

7R GDWH QR DWWHPSW KDV EHHQ PDGH WR TXDQWLI\ &DWHJRU\ DQG EHQHILWV $ &DWHJRU\ LQWDQJLEOH GHWULPHQW ZDV YDOXHG LQ 3RZHUFR XVLQJ WKH ´EDOO SDUN ILJXUHµ WHFKQLTXH +RZHYHU DV GLVFXVVHG LQ 6HFWLRQ EHORZ WKLV WHFKQLTXH KDV LWV OLPLWDWLRQV

,QMXULHV FRXOG EH EURNHQ LQWR FDWHJRULHV EDVHG RQ WKHLU GHJUHH RI VHULRXVQHVV

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 0LQLVWU\ IRU WKH (QYLURQPHQW 3URSRVHG 1DWLRQDO (QYLURQPHQWDO 6WDQGDUGV IRU

$LU 4XDOLW\ 5HVRXUFH 0DQDJHPHQW $FW 6HFWLRQ $QDO\VLV RI &RVWV DQG %HQHILWV 0LQLVWU\ IRU WKH (QYLURQPHQW KWWS ZZZ PIH JRYW Q] SXEOLFDWLRQV DLU QHV DLU VWDQGDUGV DQDO\VLV KWPO! WKH HIIHFW RI HQYLURQPHQWDO VWDQGDUGV RQ SUHPDWXUH PRUWDOLW\ KRVSLWDOLVDWLRQV DQG UHVWULFWHG DFWLYLW\ GD\V 'HV 2·'HD $Q (FRQRPLF (YDOXDWLRQ RI WKH 4XLWOLQH 1LFRWLQH 5HSODFHPHQW 7KHUDS\ 157 6HUYLFH 0LQLVWU\ RI +HDOWK :HOOLQJWRQ DW WKH HIIHFW RI D VWRS VPRNLQJ LQLWLDWLYH RQ KHDOWK RXWFRPHV 9LQFH 'UDYLW]NL 7LIIDQ\ /HVWHU DQG 6DP :LONLH 7KH 6DIHW\ %HQHILWV RI %ULJKWHU 5RDG 0DUNLQJV /DQG 7UDQVSRUW 1HZ =HDODQG :HOOLQJWRQ DQDO\VLQJ WKH HIIHFWLYHQHVV RI PDNLQJ URDG PDUNLQJV EULJKWHU

analysis. This technique uses surveys to attempt to capture individuals' utility in different health states. These utilities give a measure of the quality of life enjoyed in each of these states, relative to some benchmark health status, such as perfect health. The increase in individuals' quality of life in the factual can be multiplied by the average life expectancy to give a valuation in terms of life years gained. The measure of life years gained can then be converted into dollars, using the same techniques used to value the benefit of preventing fatalities and casualties.

Techniques for the valuation of the benefit of preventing fatalities and casualties

There are a number of techniques, including the willingness to pay approach, that can be used to calculate the value to society of preventing fatalities and casualties.

The human capital approach

The human capital approach values the benefit from avoiding a death or injury as the production that would be lost if that death or injury was to occur. Because this approach does not capture an individual's aversion to injury, or the pain, grief and suffering of those close to the casualties, it only partially captures the social cost of death or injury. Another problem with the approach is that it means that the lives of children, the elderly, women and minorities are worth less. This seems callous and inappropriate.

7KLV LV SDUWLFXODUO\ XVHIXO LQ WKH FDVH RI KHDOWK HIIHFWV DULVLQJ IURP SROOXWLRQ

$ QXPEHU RI GLIIHUHQW VXUYH\ WHFKQLTXHV DUH DYDLODEOH )RU IXUWKHU LQIRUPDWLRQ VHH .REHOW DW %RWK SK\VLFDO DQG PHQWDO KHDOWK FRQGLWLRQV FDQ EH LQFOXGHG LQ WKH DQDO\VLV

)RU H[DPSOH EUHDNLQJ DQ DUP PLJKW JLYH DQ LQGLYLGXDO SHUFHQW RI WKH XWLOLW\ WKDW WKH\ HQMR\ LQ

´SHUIHFW KHDOWKµ

2EYLRXVO\ LI TXDOLW\ RI OLIH LV RQO\ LQFUHDVHG IRU D SRUWLRQ RI LQGLYLGXDOV· OLYHV WKHQ WKLV SRUWLRQ LV WKH DSSURSULDWH YDOXH WR PXOWLSO\ WKH LQFUHDVH LQ OLIH TXDOLW\ E\

7HG 0LOODU DQG -DJDGLVK *XULD 7KH 9DOXH RI 6WDWLVWLFDO /LIH LQ 1HZ =HDODQG 0DUNHW 5HVHDUFK RQ

5RDG 6DIHW\ /DQG 7UDQVSRUW :HOOLQJWRQ DW ´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW

)RU WKRVH ZKRVH RXWSXW LV QRW SURGXFHG LQ D PDUNHW IRU H[DPSOH KRXVHZLYHV DQ HVWLPDWH KDV WR EH PDGH RI LWV YDOXH ´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW 1RWH WKDW VRPH FRPPHQWDWRUV UHVWULFW WKH KXPDQ FDSLWDO FRQFHSWLRQ WR LQFRPH HDUQHG LQ PDUNHWV IRU H[DPSOH VHH -DQH %DUQHWW 3HWHU &ORXJK DQG 9KDUL 0F:KD 7KH )XOO 6RFLDO &RVW RI 5RDG $FFLGHQWV 3DSHU SUHVHQWHG WR WKH 5RDG

6DIHW\ 5HVHDUFK 3ROLFLQJ DQG (GXFDWLRQ &RQIHUHQFH &DQEHUUD 1HZ =HDODQG ,QVWLWXWH RI (FRQRPLF

5HVHDUFK 1RYHPEHU DW 7KLV ZRXOG PHDQ WKDW SURGXFWLRQ VXFK DV XQSDLG KRXVHZRUN ZRXOG QRW EH LQFOXGHG

%DUQHWW &ORXJK DQG 0F:KD DW $V VXFK LW KDV EHHQ GHVFULEHG DV ´HPEDUUDVVLQJO\

FRQVHUYDWLYHµ 0LOODU DQG *XULD DW

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW *RRGFKLOG 6DQGHUVRQ DQG 1DQD DW 7KH OLYHV RI FKLOGUHQ DUH ZRUWK OHVV EHFDXVH WKHLU SURGXFWLRQ EHJLQV IXUWKHU LQWR WKH IXWXUH DQG VR LV VXEVWDQWLDOO\ GLVFRXQWHG 7KH OLYHV RI WKH HOGHUO\ DUH ZRUWK OHVV EHFDXVH WKHLU ODERXU PDUNHW SURGXFWLRQ KDV

The insurance approach

The benefit of avoiding a death or injury could be measured as the value of the insurance that would be payable if the death or injury was to occur. However, just like the human capital approach, there is nothing to suggest that insurance payments reflect the true costs of the death or injury. Moreover, individuals who have no insurance would unrealistically be assumed to have a zero value of life or avoidance of injury.

The implicit valuation approach

The value of public safety can be inferred from past decisions which impact upon health and safety. For example, the costs and effects of past political decisions, such as fencing swimming pools and placing health warnings on cigarette packets could be examined. The cost can be taken as a benchmark for the value of the deaths and injuries prevented. The problem with this approach is that valuations vary widely, and there is nothing to suggest that those past decisions were correct.

The willingness to pay approach

The basic tenets of this approach are set out above. In terms of public safety, a willingness to pay approach entails determining individuals' willingness to pay for incremental changes in the risk of accidental death and injury, and aggregating them to find society's willingness to pay for improvements in safety. A contingent valuation asks a representative sample of individuals what they would be prepared

HQGHG 7KH OLYHV RI ZRPHQ DQG PLQRULWLHV DUH ZRUWK OHVV EHFDXVH RQ DYHUDJH WKHLU ZDJHV WHQG WR EH ORZHU 1RWH WKDW LQ UHDOLW\ DQ DYHUDJH YDOXH PD\ EH WDNHQ DV UHSUHVHQWLQJ WKH YDOXH RI DOO OLYHV LUUHVSHFWLYH RI DJH JHQGHU RU HWKQLFLW\ 1HYHUWKHOHVV WKH OLYHV RI WKHVH GHPRJUDSKLF JURXSV ZRXOG EH LPSOLFLWO\ ZRUWK OHVV

,Q 1HZ =HDODQG WKLV LQVXUDQFH ZRXOG LQFOXGH SULYDWH LQVXUDQFH DQG DFFLGHQW FRPSHQVDWLRQ SD\PHQWV

%DUQHWW &ORXJK DQG 0F:KD DW

,ELG

,ELG

%\ IROORZLQJ WKHVH GHFLVLRQV DQ\ PLVWDNHV PDGH LQ WKH SDVW ZLOO EH SHUSHWXDWHG

%DUQHWW &ORXJK DQG 0F:KD DW $VNLQJ DQ LQGLYLGXDO ZKDW WKH\ ZRXOG SD\ WR DYRLG FHUWDLQ GHDWK ZRXOG EH XQZRUNDEOH EHFDXVH XVXDOO\ WKH\ ZRXOG EH SUHSDUHG WR SD\ IDU LQ H[FHVV RI WKHLU WRWDO ZHDOWK SHRSOH ZRXOG EH SUHSDUHG WR ERUURZ DVN IRU FKDULW\ IURP RWKHUV DQG SRVVLEO\ HYHQ VWHDO WR VWD\ DOLYH

to pay for certain increases in public safety. An observational valuation looks at things that are expected to reveal preferences for safety; for example the rate at which individuals change their tyres, or wage differentials for those in risky jobs. However, for much of this behaviour there are no reliable data, or the data that are available do not reflect individual preferences because government regulations distort individuals' choices. Therefore, in practice willingness to pay for public safety is most easily measured through surveys of stated preferences.

An example of a willingness to pay approach to the evaluation of public safety: valuing the prevention of fatalities and casualties on New Zealand roads

Land Transport New Zealand (“LTNZ”) appears to be the only New Zealand agency which has attempted to put a value on saving a life. A fatality is currently valued at $3,046,700, a serious injury at $304,700, and a minor injury at $12,200. This is based on a survey of New Zealand residents undertaken in 1989 and 1990 by Ted Millar and Jagadish Guria on behalf of what was then the Land Transport Safety Authority (“LTSA”).

Millar and Guria used a contingent valuation methodology to calculate monetary estimates for individuals' willingness to pay to avoid fatalities and casualties. People were asked to state how much they would pay for different goods and services which would reduce their risk of death and injury on the roads. The value of statistical life was then calculated by dividing the average willingness to pay by the reduction in risk. The loss of quality of life due to serious and minor injuries is set at 10 percent and 0.4 percent respectively, of the value of statistical

,ELG DW

,ELG DW *RRGFKLOG 6DQGHUVRQ DQG 1DQD DW

%DUQHWW &ORXJK DQG 0F:KD DW

,W XVHV WKH YDOXDWLRQ WR DVVLVW LQ DQDO\VLQJ ZKHWKHU SDUWLFXODU WUDQVSRUW SURMHFWV VKRXOG EH XQGHUWDNHQ

7KLV LV FRPPRQO\ UHIHUUHG WR LQ WKH OLWHUDWXUH DV WKH YDOXH RI VWDWLVWLFDO OLIH 9R6/

0LQLVWU\ RI 7UDQVSRUW 7KH 6RFLDO &RVWV RI 5RDG &UDVKHV DQG ,QMXULHV -XQH 8SGDWH 0LQLVWU\ RI 7UDQVSRUW :HOOLQJWRQ DW 7KHVH YDOXHV GR QRW LQFOXGH WKH PHGLFDO DQG OHJDO FRVWV RI WKH IDWDOLW\ RU FDVXDOW\

0LOODU DQG *XULD ,Q DQRWKHU VXUYH\ ZDV FRQGXFWHG *XULD HW DO ,W ZDV PRUH FRPSUHKHQVLYH WKDQ LWV SUHGHFHVVRU *XULD HW DO DW 7KH VWDWLVWLFDO YDOXH RI OLIH EDVHG RQ ZLOOLQJQHVV WR SD\ ILJXUHV ZDV IRXQG WR EH PLOOLRQ *XULD HW DO DW 7KLV KDV QRW \HW EHHQ DGRSWHG E\ WKH 0LQLVWU\ RI 7UDQVSRUW LQ WKHLU HYDOXDWLRQ RI URDG VDIHW\ SURMHFWV

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW

,ELG DW )RU H[DPSOH RQH RI WKH TXHVWLRQV DVNHG SHRSOH KRZ PXFK WROO WKH\ ZRXOG SD\ WR WDNH D RQH ZD\ WULS RI NP RQ D URDG WKDW UHGXFHG WKHLU ULVN RI G\LQJ LQ DQ DFFLGHQW IURP LQ WR

LQ $SSHQGL[ 7ZR DW

*RRGFKLOG 6DQGHUVRQ DQG 1DQD DW )RU H[DPSOH LI DQ LQGLYLGXDO LV ZLOOLQJ WR VSHQG

WR UHGXFH WKHLU ULVN RI G\LQJ E\ WKHLU VWDWLVWLFDO YDOXH RI OLIH LV PLOOLRQ

life. These valuations of death and injury are updated regularly to reflect changes in individual earnings, on the assumption that willingness to pay will vary with ability to pay.

The richer an economy is, the more its citizens can be expected to be prepared to pay for life and injury saving measures. Values of statistical life for a number of countries, as published in a 1993 Economist article, suggest that the New Zealand value is very much in line with estimates for countries of similar income per capita.

Putting it all together: evaluating public safety benefits

In the road safety context

Fletcher Challenge dealt with a claim of increased road safety from a reduction in road usage. Although the applicant quantified the benefits from reduced road usage, this figure may have pertained to the reduced road maintenance costs. If such a case was to come before the Commission now, the LTSA's estimates for the value of statistical life and avoidance of injury could be multiplied by the number of fatalities and casualties avoided, to determine the safety benefit. There are studies available that would assist in estimating the number of casualties and fatalities avoided as a consequence of a reduction in road usage.

In other contexts

The LTSA's figures could also be used as an approximation of the benefit arising from the prevention of fatalities and casualties in other public safety contexts.

0LQLVWU\ RI 7UDQVSRUW DW

%DUQHWW &ORXJK DQG 0F:KD DW /DQG 7UDQVSRUW 1HZ =HDODQG

*DYLQ )LVKHU HW DO +HDOWK DQG $LU 3ROOXWLRQ LQ 1HZ =HDODQG &KULVWFKXUFK 3LORW 6WXG\ 0LQLVWU\ RI 7UDQVSRUW KWWS ZZZ WUDQVSRUW JRYW Q] SDJH ! DFFHVVHG 6HSWHPEHU

´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW

)LVKHU HW DO

)OHWFKHU &KDOOHQJH DW > @ > @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 'HSDUWPHQW RI 7UDQVSRUWDWLRQ ´5RDG 8VDJH DQG 6DIHW\µ LQ :DVKLQJWRQ 6WDWH 'DWD %RRN 2IILFH RI )LQDQFLDO 0DQDJHPHQW 6WDWH RI :DVKLQJWRQ

KWWS ZZZ RIP ZD JRY GDWDERRN WUDQVSRUWDWLRQ WW DVS! DFFHVVHG 6HSWHPEHU

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW 0LOODU DQG *XULD VWDWH WKDW RYHUVHDV UHVHDUFK VXJJHVWV WKDW WKH YDOXHV FRXOG EH DSSOLFDEOH WR RWKHU FRQWH[WV

They have already been used in a number of studies for this purpose. The real difficulty lies in determining the number of fatalities and casualties avoided as a result of the safety improvement. Studies could potentially be of assistance. Where benefits result in improved life quality, rather than avoided fatalities or injuries, cost utility analysis can be utilised to calculate a valuation in terms of life years saved. It is important to note that other economic costs, avoided as a result of the benefit occurring would also need to be included in the analysis.

Critique of the approach

The cost, time and complexity of the Commission or an applicant undertaking a study to value life and the avoidance of injuries would be prohibitive. However, these burdens need not be incurred, because the estimates of the LTSA can be utilised.

Whilst theoretically very sound, the willingness to pay approach has difficulties in application. It is very hard for people to put values on tiny changes in probabilities that are already very small. However, the fact that the value of statistical life revealed by reported speed choice was consistent with that revealed by the willingness to pay questions, suggests that the respondents did understand the risk levels in the willingness to pay questions. A further problem lies in the fact that it is difficult for those who have never been seriously injured to know how much they would like to avoid it.

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 0LQLVWU\ IRU WKH (QYLURQPHQW FDOFXODWLQJ WKH KHDOWK EHQHILWV IURP SURSRVHG HQYLURQPHQWDO VWDQGDUGV )LVKHU HW DO FDOFXODWLQJ WKH KHDOWK FRVWV RI SROOXWLRQ LQ &KULVWFKXUFK %ULDQ (DVWRQ 7KH 6RFLDO &RVWV RI 7REDFFR 8VH DQG $OFRKRO 0LVXVH 3XEOLF +HDOWK 0RQRJUDSK 6HULHV 1R :HOOLQJWRQ 6FKRRO RI 0HGLFLQH :HOOLQJWRQ DW

FDOFXODWLQJ WKH VRFLDO FRVWV RI WREDFFR DQG PLVXVH 2·'HD DQG 7XFNHU DW FDOFXODWLQJ WKH VRFLDO FRVWV RI VXLFLGH 7KHLU SRWHQWLDO XVHIXOQHVV KDV DOVR EHHQ QRWHG LQ WKH FRQWH[W RI HYDOXDWLQJ WKH KHDOWK EHQHILWV IURP FDPSDLJQV WR UHGXFH WKH LQFLGHQFH RI VNLQ FDQFHU &DQFHU 6RFLHW\ &DQFHU 8SGDWH LQ 3UDFWLFH ,VVXH &DQFHU 6RFLHW\ :HOOLQJWRQ ,Q VRPH LQVWDQFHV D YDOXH RI VWDWLVWLFDO OLIH \HDU KDV EHHQ FDOFXODWHG IRU H[DPSOH VHH 0LQLVWU\ IRU WKH (QYLURQPHQW 2·'HD

DW 7KLV DOORZV EHQHILWV DULVLQJ IURP DQ LQFUHDVH LQ OLIH H[SHFWDQF\ RU DQ LPSURYHG TXDOLW\ RI OLIH WR EH FDOFXODWHG

)RU H[DPSOH WKH HIIHFWV RI HQYLURQPHQWDO VWDQGDUGV DQG KHDOWK SROLFLHV KDYH EHHQ TXDQWLILHG

0LQLVWU\ IRU WKH (QYLURQPHQW 2·'HD DW

7KH OLIH \HDUV VDYHG ZLOO EH PXOWLSOLHG E\ WKH YDOXH RI D VWDWLVWLFDO OLIH \HDU UDWKHU WKDQ WKH YDOXH RI D VWDWLVWLFDO OLIH

)RU H[DPSOH FRVWV WR WKH SXEOLF KHDOWK V\VWHP RI WUHDWLQJ WKH LQMXULHV RU FRQGLWLRQV

´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW REHOW DW

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW 7KLV LV EHFDXVH UHVSRQGHQWV GLG QRW QHHG WR XQGHUVWDQG VPDOO ULVN OHYHOV WR DQVZHU WKH VSHHG FKRLFH TXHVWLRQV

´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW REHOW DW

The values calculated by the LTSA related to risks where people felt in control. In their report, the LTSA suggested that higher values may be appropriate for risks people feel are outside their control, such as environmental exposures, occupational incidents, and airline and public transport crashes.

A common objection to valuing public safety is that it is morally offensive to reduce human life to dollars and cents. However, it is not as callous as it sounds. Individuals do it implicitly all the time. For example, a driver takes a chance of being killed in a car, but judges the speed and convenience to be worth the risk. Furthermore, whenever the government issues regulations or allocates resources that affect health and safety, it too values our lives.

4.4 The “ball-park figure” technique

The “ball-park figure” approach to valuation involves coming up with a value for the benefit accruing to an individual, and then scaling it up to arrive at an estimate of the total benefit. The distinguishing feature of this technique is that there is no basis for the number adopted as representing the value of the benefit accruing to an individual. No reference is made to surveys or studies; rather the number is seemingly plucked out of the air.

The Commission has taken a ball-park figure approach to the quantification of intangible benefits on two occasions. In Qantas, it was used to value the scheduling benefits to travellers under the proposed alliance between Qantas and Air New Zealand. The Commission assumed that on average, business and leisure travellers would receive a 20 percent gain from scheduling benefits. This was applied to an assumed opportunity cost of $100 per hour for business travellers,

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW

,ELG 6HH DOVR )LVKHU HW DO ,Q RWKHU ZRUGV WKH YDOXH RI OLIH PLJKW QRW EH LQGHSHQGHQW RI WKH FDXVH RI GHDWK

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW

´7KH 3ULFH RI /LIHµ 'HFHPEHU DW

0LOODU DQG *XULD DW

$VVXPLQJ WKDW &DWHJRU\ EHQHILWV FRQVWLWXWH LQWDQJLEOHV

7KLV ZDV VLJQLILFDQWO\ ORZHU WKDQ WKH SHUFHQW JDLQ DVVXPHG E\ $LU 1HZ =HDODQG DQG 4DQWDV

4DQWDV DW > @ > @

and $20 per hour for leisure travellers, to arrive at a total benefit of

$476,000, which was rounded off to $500,000. On appeal, the High Court did not criticise the Commission's approach.

In NZRFU 1 and NZRFU 2, the NZRFU suggested that the benefit accruing to television viewers from a more attractive National Provincial Competition (NPC), could be evaluated using the ball-park figure technique. For example, in NZRFU 1 it was suggested that the increased attractiveness of a more even game might be valued at between 50 cents and $10 per person viewing. Even at a figure of only 50 cents, the public benefit would still total $2.5 million per year. The Chairman and Commissioners Auton and Stapleton accepted this general approach. Commissioner Harrison on the other hand, thought that the intangible and subjective nature of the benefit meant that it should not be quantified. The Commission in NZRFU 2 rejected the technique in favour of a more elaborate economic model suggesting that, “[t]he difficulty with this approach is that it is fairly ad hoc; no sound reasoning was provided by the Applicant as to why this was a sensible range for the net benefits that may accrue”.

The ball-park figure technique has also been used to evaluate a Category 2C detriment. As discussed in Section 2.3, in Powerco the Commission, whilst recognising that the social detriment associated with redundancy could not be quantified with any accuracy, came up with a rough figure to demonstrate the impact that it would have on the public benefit assessment. It assumed that on average, the social cost was $10,000 per person made redundant. If forty people were made redundant, the total cost would be $400,000. This figure was then

,ELG $UJXDEO\ DYHUDJH ZDJH UDWHV FRXOG SURYLGH DW OHDVW D SDUWLDO EDVLV IRU WKHVH ILJXUHV

,ELG DW > @ > @

,ELG DW > @ > @

4DQWDV +& DW > @ > @

1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @ 1=5)8 DW > @ > @ > @ > @

1=5)8 DW > @

,ELG ,Q 1=5)8 LW ZDV VXJJHVWHG WKDW WKH EHQHILW WR WKH DYHUDJH LQGLYLGXDO YLHZHU ZDV EHWZHHQ

DQG HTXDWLQJ WR D WRWDO EHQHILW RI EHWZHHQ PLOOLRQ DQG PLOOLRQ 1=5)8 DW

> @

1=5)8 DW > @ +RZHYHU EHFDXVH RI WKH UHODWLYHO\ ZHDN QH[XV EHWZHHQ WKH 5HJXODWLRQV DQG WKH LQFUHDVHG DWWUDFWLYHQHVV RI WKH 13& WKH\ IHOW WKDW WKH HVWLPDWH ZDV PRUH OLNHO\ WR EH DW WKH ORZHU HQG RI WKH UDQJH

,ELG 7KH &RPPLVVLRQHUV WRRN WKH VDPH SRVLWLRQV WR WKH EHQHILW DULVLQJ IURP JUHDWHU DXGLHQFH HQMR\PHQW RI 1HZ =HDODQG LQWHUQDWLRQDO PDWFKHV ,ELG DW > @ > @

1=5)8 DW > @ 7KH &RPPLVVLRQ DGDSWHG WKH VSHFWDWRU GHPDQG PRGHO WKDW WKH\ KDG XVHG WR TXDQWLI\ WKH LQFUHDVHG HQMR\PHQW DFFUXLQJ WR VSHFWDWRUV

,ELG

3RZHUFR DW > @

rounded off to $500,000 and weighed against the other quantified benefits and detriments. Presumably this same technique could be used to value a social benefit.

4.4.2 CRITIQUE OF THE APPROACH

As the comments of the Commission in NZRFU 2 highlight, the ball-park figure technique has no sound evidential basis and so the values it produces for the benefits may well be inaccurate. NZRFU 2 illustrates that where there is a preferable alternative that has an economic basis for its assumptions, the ball-park figure technique will not be used. Where there is no such alternative, arguably the ball-park technique could be useful to the extent that it focuses the Commission's attention on the magnitude that the benefit could have. However, it is questionable how such an arbitrary valuation can be of much assistance. Whilst the Commission in Ansett recognised the usefulness of quantification, it cautioned against the temptation to accept “spurious quantification[s]”. If numbers are simply plucked out of the air, quantification loses its advantages of objectivity and transparency. Qualitative analysis is preferable to a ball-park figure analysis.

4.5 Conclusion

The quantification of intangible benefits is no easy task. Economic models may be of assistance in a limited number of cases. The costs and the lack of data will be prohibitive in many instances. The willingness to pay approach may provide a relatively accurate and cheap method of quantification where there have been sufficient studies to base the analysis on. Where all else fails, the ball-park figure technique is available. Given the complete lack of basis for its assumptions, its use in place of qualitative analysis is questionable at best.

,ELG DW > @ 0RUH VSHFLILFDOO\ LW ZDV GHGXFWHG IURP WKH EHQHILW DFFUXLQJ IURP UDWLRQDOLVDWLRQ

1=5)8 DW > @

$QG VR UHVXOWV LQ JUHDWHU WUDQVSDUHQF\

$QVHWW DW > @

Conclusion

Evaluating the treatment of the class of benefits termed “intangible” by the Commission, necessitates classifying benefits as tangible or intangible. This is a difficult task that has been exacerbated by the apparent lack of agreement, even amongst Commissioners, as to the precise meaning of the term “intangible benefit”. Whilst the current Guidelines and the preponderance of decisions suggest that intangibility hinges upon a benefit's ease of quantification, some decisions seem to implicitly equate intangibility with quantification per se. This difference in definition, combined with the difficulty of applying the definitions, leads to inconsistencies in classification. Consequently, it is impossible to say with precision which benefits are tangible and which are intangible. This dissertation overcomes this classification problem by utilising a spectrum of tangibility within which to evaluate the treatment of less tangible and more tangible benefits.

To date, negligible weight has been attached to the most intangible benefits. This treatment is usually justified by evidential problems, which largely stem from the intangibility of the benefit itself. Whilst it is difficult to discern a change in the treatment of intangibles over time, the Commission appears more willing to discuss intangibles than in the past, even raising them itself in one recent decision. There is some indication that more weight is accorded to quantified intangibles, providing an incentive to applicants to quantify intangible claims. However, quantification is a difficult task - issues of cost and reliability rendering it impracticable in many instances.

Under the current law, intangible benefits must be considered in the application of the public benefit test, unless the intangibility means that the applicant cannot satisfy its evidentiary burden of proving the benefit. As a matter of policy, it would

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ

7HDP7DON DW > @ 5XDSHKX DW > @ 2PY DW > @ 4DQWDV DW > @ 1=5)8 DW > @

)RU H[DPSOH VHH 5XDSHKX ,QWHUHVWLQJO\ WKH &KLHI (FRQRPLVW RI WKH &RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ 'U 0LFKDHO 3LFNIRUG VHHPV WR VXSSRUW D WHVW EDVHG RQ TXDQWLILFDWLRQ SHU VH (PDLO IURP 'U 0LFKDHO

3LFNIRUG $XJXVW

&DWHJRU\ DQG EHQHILWV

4DQWDV DW > @

6HH 3RZHUFR LQ SDUWLFXODU

7KLV LV SDUWLFXODUO\ VR IRU WKH PRUH LQWDQJLEOH EHQHILWV &DWHJRULHV DQG

be inappropriate to exclude intangibles from the balancing process. It would raise a complex definitional problem and exclude some issues that are of real concern to society.

The distinction drawn by the Commission between tangible and intangible benefits does not seem to be a particularly useful one, particularly given the Commission's sporadic and inconsistent use of the term. Because nothing hinges on the distinction, it is of little or no assistance to applicants or the Commission. The key focus for the Commission in determining the weight to be given to intangible benefits seems to be the evidential problems flowing from intangibility, rather than the intangibility per se. Focusing upon whether a given benefit is tangible or intangible unnecessarily complicates the public benefit analysis. It may be best if the Commission recognises this by doing away with the distinction, and instead focusing upon the core requirements for proving a benefit. Because the Commission often draws on the principles set out in the Guidelines in its decisions, an important first step towards abolishing the distinction would be to remove it from the Guidelines.

7KH UHTXLUHPHQWV RI SURYLQJ D FDXVDO QH[XV DQG SURYLGLQJ HYLGHQFH RI WKH H[WHQW RI WKH EHQHILW

&RPPHUFH &RPPLVVLRQ

Bibliography

BOOKS

Anderson, David, Sweeney, Dennis and Williams, Thomas, Quantitative Methods for Business (10th ed, Thomson South-Western, Belmont, 2006)

Clarke, Philip and Corones, Stephen, Competition Law and Policy: Cases and Materials (Oxford University Press, Melbourne, 1999)

Commerce Clearing House, New Zealand Business Law Guide, Volume 1 (Commerce Clearing House, Auckland, 1998-2006)

Corones Stephen, Competition Law in Australia (3rd ed, Lawbook Co, Sydney, 2004)

Deegan, Craig and Samkin, Grant, New Zealand Financial Accounting (3rd ed, McGraw-Hill Book Company, Melbourne, 2006)

Dinwiddy, Caroline and Teal, Francis, The Two-Sector General Equilibrium Model: A New Approach (Philip Alan Publishers, New York, 1988)

Dixon, Peter and Rimmer, Maureen, Dynamic, General Equilibrium Modelling for Forecasting and Policy: A Practical Guide and Documentation of MONASH (North- Holland, Amsterdam, 2002)

Drummond, Michael, O'Brien, Bernie, Stoddart, Greg and Torrance, George, Methods for the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programmes (Oxford University Press, New York, 1997)

Frank, Robert and Bernanke, Ben, Principles of Economics (3rd ed, McGraw Hill Irwin, Boston, 2007)

Greer, Douglas, Efficiency and Competition: Alternative, Complementary or

Conflicting Objectives (Research Monograph 47, New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, Wellington, 1989)

Hertel, Thomas (ed), Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications (Cambridge University Press, New York, 1997)

Kobelt, Gisela, Health Economics: An Introduction to Economic Evaluation (Office of Health Economics, London, 1996)

Krugman, Paul and Obstfeld, Maurice, International Economics: Theory and Policy

(7th ed, Pearson Addison Wesley, Boston, 2006)

The Concise Oxford Dictionary (8WK ed, Oxford University Press, New York, 1990)

van Roy Yvonne, Guidebook to New Zealand: Competition Laws (CCH New Zealand, Auckland, 1991)

Varian, Hal, Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach (7th ed, WW Norton, New York, 2006)

Zerbe, Richard, Economic Efficiency in Law and Economics (Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, 2001)

ARTICLES AND CHAPTERS IN BOOKS

Ahdar, Rex, “Authorisation and Public Benefit under the Commerce Act 1986: Some Emerging Principles” (1988) 16 Australian Business Law Review 128

Ahdar, Rex, “The Authorisation Process and the “Public Benefit” Test” in Ahdar, Rex (ed), Competition Law & Policy in New Zealand (The Law Book Company, Sydney, 1991) 217

Ahdar, Rex, “Consumers, Redistribution of Income and the Purpose of Competition Law” [2002] European Competition Law Review 341

Begg, Susan and Jennings, Stephen, “Assessment of the Commerce Act in terms of Economic Principles” in Bollard, Alan (ed) The Economics of the Commerce Act (Research Monograph 52, New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, 1989) 1

Begg, Susan and Wilkinson, Bryce, “Goals of Antitrust Policy and the Commerce Act” in Berry, Mark and Evans, Lewis (eds), Competition Law at the Turn of the Century: A New Zealand Perspective (Victoria University Press, Wellington, 2003) 61

Bertram, Geoff, “What's Wrong with New Zealand's Public Benefit Test?” (2004) 38(2) New Zealand Economic Papers 265

Brodley, Joseph, “The Economic Goals of Antitrust: Efficiency, Consumer Welfare, and Technological Progress” (1987) New York University Law Review 1020

Duggan, Shelly, “Sporting Entities and Trade Practices Law: What is Best and Fairest?” (1999) 7 Trade Practices Law Journal 201

Duns, John, “Competition Law and Public Benefits” (1994) 16 Adelaide Law Review

245

Easton, Brian, “The Public Interest in Competition Policy” in Bollard, Alan (ed) The Economics of the Commerce Act (Research Monograph 52, New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, 1989) 66

Evans, Lewis, “Economic Measurement and the Authorisation Process: The Expanding Place of Quantitative Analysis” (1999) 7 Competition and Consumer Law Journal 99

Fels, Allan and Grimwade, Tim, “Authorisation: Is it Still Relevant to Australian Competition Law?” (2003) 11 Competition and Consumer Law Journal 187

Hazledine, Tim, “Application of the Public Benefit Test to the Air New

Zealand/Qantas Case” (2004) 38(2) New Zealand Economic Papers 279

Officer, Robert and Williams, Philip, “The Public Benefit Test in an Authorisation Decision” in Richardson, Megan and Williams, Philip (eds), The Law and the Market (The Federation Press, Sydney, 1995) 157

Pickford, Michael, “Competition Policy, Mergers and the Net Social Benefit Test” in Bollard, Alan (ed) The Economics of the Commerce Act (Research Monograph 52, New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, 1989) 89

Pickford, Michael, “The Evaluation of Public Benefit and Detriment under the Commerce Act 1986” (1993) 27(2) New Zealand Economic Papers 209

Pickford, Michael, “Assessing Public Benefits and Detriments” (1997) Compliance

15

Smith, Rhonda and Grimwade, Timothy, “Authorisation: Some Issues” (1997) 25

Australian Business Law Review 351

Smith, Rhonda, “Authorisation and the Trade Practices Act: More about Public Benefit” (2003) 11 Competition and Consumer Law Journal 21

Stevens, Lyn, “The Goals of the Commerce Act” in Berry, Mark and Evans, Lewis (eds) Competition Law at the Turn of the Century: A New Zealand Perspective (Victoria University Press, Wellington, 2003) 61

“The Price of Life” (4 December 1993) The Economist 76

PAPERS AND REPORTS

Barnett, Jane, Clough, Peter and McWha, Vhari, The Full Social Cost of Road Accidents (Paper presented to the Road Safety Research, Policing and Education Conference, Canberra, New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, November 1999)

Bollard, Alan, An Economic Comment on the Commerce Act Review (New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, Wellington, 1989)

Bollard, Alan, Notes on Quantification of Public Benefit in the Context of the Commerce Act (New Zealand Institute of Economic Research, Wellington, 1993)

Collinge, John, Determining Public Interest under the Commerce Act: A Review to Date (Occasional Paper No 1, Commerce Commission, Wellington, 1987) 39

Department of Trade and Industry, A Discussion Paper: Review of the Commerce Act 1986 (Department of Trade and Industry, Wellington, 1988)

Department of Transportation, “Road Usage and Safety” in State of Washington, Washington State Data Book (2005) Office of Financial Management, State of Washington <http://www.ofm.wa.gov/databook/transportation/tt02.asp> accessed 16 September 2006

Dravitzki, Vince, Lester, Tiffany and Wilkie, Sam, The Safety Benefits of Brighter Road Markings (Land Transport New Zealand, Wellington, 2005)

Easton, Brian, The Social Costs of Tobacco Use and Alcohol Misuse (Public Health Monograph Series No 2, Wellington School of Medicine, Wellington, 1997)

Fels, Allan, The Public Benefit Test in the Trade Practices Act 1974 (National Competition Policy Workshop, Melbourne, 12 July 2001)

Fisher, Gavin et al, Health and Air Pollution in New Zealand: Christchurch Pilot Study (2005) Ministry of Transport <http://www.transport.govt.nz/page-151> accessed 1 September 2006

Gale, Stephen, Pieces of String: Quantification and the Commerce Act (Paper presented at the 8th Annual Workshop of the Competition Law and Policy Institute of New Zealand, Wellington, 1-3 August 1997)

Goodchild, Mark, Sanderson, Kel and Nana, Ganesh, Measuring the Total Cost of Injury in New Zealand: A Review of Alternative Cost Methodologies (Report prepared for the Department of Labour, Business and Economic Research, Wellington, 2002)

Guria, Jagadish et al, The New Zealand Values of Statistical Life and of the Prevention of Injuries (Draft report, 2003)

Jennings, Stephen and Begg, Susan, An Economic Review of Commerce

Commission Decisions under the Commerce Act 1986 (Report prepared for the Treasury, Jarden & Co, Wellington, 1988)

Millar, Ted and Guria, Jagadish, The Value of Statistical Life in New Zealand: Market Research on Road Safety (Land Transport, Wellington, 1991)

Ministry for the Environment, Proposed National Environmental Standards for Air Quality Resource Management Act Section 32: Analysis of Costs and Benefits

(2004) Ministry for the Environment <http://www.mfe.govt.nz/publications/air/nes- air - standards - analysis/html> accessed 5 September 2006

Ministry of Commerce, Reports and Decisions: Review of the Commerce Act 1986

(Ministry of Commerce, Wellington, 1989)

Ministry of Commerce, The Treasury, Department of Justice and Department of the Prime Minister and Cabinet, Review of the Commerce Act 1986: Discussion Document (Ministry of Commerce, Wellington, 1991)

Ministry of Commerce, The Treasury, Department of Justice and Department of the Prime Minister and Cabinet, Review of the Commerce Act 1986 (Ministry of Commerce, Wellington, 1992)

Ministry of Economic Development, A Guide to Preparing Regulatory Impact Statements (1999) Ministry of Economic Development

<http://www.med.govt.nz/templates/MultipageDocumentTOC 6 0 7 . aspx> accessed 3 August 2006

Ministry of Transport, The Social Cost of Road Crashes and Injuries: June 2006 Update (Ministry of Transport, Wellington, 2006)

Murray-North, The Economic Determinants of Domestic Travel in New Zealand (New Zealand Tourism and Publicity Department, Wellington, 1989)

O'Dea, Des, An Economic Evaluation of the Quitline Nicotine Replacement Therapy (NRT) Service (Ministry of Health, Wellington, 2004)

O'Dea, Des and Tucker, Sarah, The Cost of Suicide to Society (Ministry of Health, Wellington, 2005)

Pickford, Michael, The Evaluation of Public Benefit and Detriment under the

Commerce Act (Occasional Paper No 7, Commerce Commission, Wellington, 1998) The Treasury, Cost Benefit Analysis Primer (The Treasury, Wellington, 2005)

Williams, David, Ricketts, Geoff and Quinn, Frank, The Commerce Act (New Zealand Law Society Seminar, 1986)

NEW ZEALAND COMMERCE COMMISSION AND AUSTRALIAN COMPETITION AND CONSUMER COMMISSION GUIDELINES

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Guide to Authorisations and Notifications (Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Canberra, 1995)

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Guide to Authorisation: Draft for Comment (Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Canberra, 2006)

Commerce Commission, Analysis of public benefits and balancing them against detriments arising from substantial lessening of competition/acquisition or strengthening of a dominant position (Exposure Draft, Commerce Commission, Wellington, 1993)

Commerce Commission, Guidelines to the Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments in the Context of the Commerce Act (Commerce Commission, Wellington, 1994)

Commerce Commission, Guidelines to the Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments (Commerce Commission, Wellington, 1997)

HANSARD

Burdon, Philip (1990) 508 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 2222-2223 (Commerce Law Reform Bill: Report of the Commerce and Marketing Committee)

“Commerce Amendment Bill, Fair Trading Amendment Bill, Dumping and Countervailing Duties Amendment Bill: Third Readings” (1990) 508 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 2418-2423

“Commerce Bill: Report of the Commerce and Marketing Committee” (1986) 468

New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 8589-8599

“Commerce Bill: Second Reading” (1986) 469 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates

506-517, 670-685

“Commerce Bill: Second Reading” (1986) 470 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates

815-822

“Commerce Bill: Third Reading” (1986) 470 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates

1173-1183, 1264-1269

“Commerce Law Reform Bill: Report of the Commerce and Marketing Committee” (1990) 508 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 2220-2228

“Commerce Law Reform Bill: Second Reading” (1990) 508 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 2396-2412

Cullen, Hon Dr Michael (2006) 631 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 3195- 3208 (Budget Statement)

Matthewson, Clive (1986) 470 New Zealand Parliamentary Debates 1265-1267 (Commerce Bill: Third Reading)

INTERNET RESOURCES

Birch, Rt Hon Bill, Budget Policy Statement 1995 (1995) The Treasury

<http://www.treasury.govt/pubs/bmb/policy.htm accessed 22 September 2006

Commerce Commission, Overview Commerce Commission

<http://www.comcom.govt.nz/TheCommission/Overview.aspx> accessed 23

August 2006

Department of the Prime Minister and Cabinet, Government Priorities Department of the Prime Minister and Cabinet

<http://www.dpmc.govt.nz/dpmc/publications/government-priorities.html> accessed 20 September 2006

Land Transport New Zealand, Putting a Price on Life (1999) Land Transport New

Zealand <http://www.landtransport.govt.nz/publications/rsnz/1999/mar-04.html> accessed 30 August 2006

OTHER

Cancer Society, Cancer Update in Practice (Issue 2, Cancer Society, Wellington, 2000)

Cartwright, Dame Silvia, Speech from the Throne (Speech delivered at the State Opening of Parliament, Wellington, 8 November 2005)

Email from Dr Michael Pickford to Jill Caughey (22 August 2006) Email from Dr Michael Pickford to Jill Caughey (21 September 2006)

Interview with Dr Niven Winchester, Lecturer, Department of Economics, University of Otago (Dunedin, 21 September 2006)

Legal Services Agency, Law Access Catalogue (6th ed, Legal Services Agency, Wellington, 2002)


NZLII: Copyright Policy | Disclaimers | Privacy Policy | Feedback
URL: http://www.nzlii.org/nz/journals/UOtaLawTD/2006/2.html